Journal of Game Theory

p-ISSN: 2325-0046    e-ISSN: 2325-0054

2018;  7(1): 7-16

doi:10.5923/j.jgt.20180701.02

 

Indirect Taxation and Privatization in a Model of Government’s Tax Preference

Kangsik Choi1, Min Hwan Lee2

1Graduate School of International Studies, Pusan National University, Busan, Korea

2College of Business Administration, Inha University, Incheon, Korea

Correspondence to: Min Hwan Lee, College of Business Administration, Inha University, Incheon, Korea.

Email:

Copyright © 2018 Scientific & Academic Publishing. All Rights Reserved.

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY).
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Abstract

By introducing government preferences for tax revenues into a unionized mixed duopoly, this study investigates how such preferences can change a government’s choice of indirect tax regimes between ad valorem and specific taxes. The main results are as follows. Given that one of the tax regimes is predetermined, privatization never improves welfare and is preferable for the government when the preference of tax revenue is high. However, when the tax regime is endogenously determined by the government, privatization is preferable from the viewpoint of social welfare if the government heavily emphasizes tax revenue. Thus, there are conflicts of interest between the public firm and the government: If it heavily emphasizes tax revenue, then the government always has an incentive to levy specific tax, while the public firm has an incentive to be levied ad valorem tax. However, there are no conflicts of interest between the public firm and the government when the government levies specific tax, even though it places less emphasis on tax revenue” or “when the government levies specific tax, but the preference for tax revenue is sufficiently when the government levies specific tax, even though it places less emphasis on tax revenue Interestingly, the government never has an incentive for privatization when considering either tax as an option.

Keywords: Ad Valorem Tax, Specific Tax, Government’s Payoff, Social Welfare, Privatization

Cite this paper: Kangsik Choi, Min Hwan Lee, Indirect Taxation and Privatization in a Model of Government’s Tax Preference, Journal of Game Theory, Vol. 7 No. 1, 2018, pp. 7-16. doi: 10.5923/j.jgt.20180701.02.

1. Introduction

It is well known that ad valorem taxes dominate specific taxes from the welfare perspective as evidenced by Seade (1985) and Delipalla and Keen (1992), among others (see also Keen’s (1998) comprehensive survey paper). Surprisingly, in the literature on mixed oligopoly, there have been few analyses of socially optimal taxation that weigh the advantages of ad valorem and specific taxes. Mujumdar and Pal (1998) exceptionally showed that privatization could increase both social welfare and tax revenues, and that an increase in tax does not change the total output but increases the output of the public firm and tax revenues.
As stated above, concerning private firms, canonical arguments on the comparison of ad valorem and specific taxes implicitly assume that the government’s (or social planner’s) objective is to maximize social welfare. On the other hand, the public firm’s welfare-maximizing behavior is assumed to support the objective of benevolent government. Thus, it is generally understood that the public firm, as well as the government, traditionally maximizes the sum of tax revenues or subsidies and the consumer and producer surpluses. However, in the real world, some conflicts of interest exist between the public firm in an industry and the government. For example, Vickers and Yarrow (1988, p. 128) argue that “Ministers were left to free to adopt their own definition of the public interest…, and there have been frequent political interventions to influence operational decision making.”
In this regard, other views on the objective of the government exist in the literature, including that the government maximizes tax revenue for its own private agenda or that it is intrinsically a tax-revenue maximizer (e.g., Besley, 2006; Brennan and Buchanan, 1980; Niskanen, 1971). It is often argued that the political structure of a country plays a role in determining the government’s objective function. Edwards and Keen (1996) and Wilson (2005) argued that a Leviathan government tends to maximize its net tax revenue to increase government size so that more revenue is at the government’s disposal. A number of empirical studies also provide evidence in support of tax revenue maximization by the government (see Caplan, 2001; Zax, 1989; Nelson, 1987). Therefore, we investigate how tax preference can change the government’s choice of tax regimes between ad valorem and specific taxes when the public firm and the government have different objective functions in a model of mixed duopoly.
The economic analyses of the government are divided into two broad aspects. One aspect emphasizes that the government operates in public interest. The other is that the government often sets targets for tax revenue collection and formulates tax policies accordingly. We therefore strive to understand a view of the government that lies between these two extremes. Our goal is to investigate whether the dominance of ad valorem taxes over specific taxes holds when the objective of the government is to maximize both social welfare and tax revenues. None of the previous studies have demonstrated the possible implications of the dominance of indirect tax schemes when the government has such an objective function1. This study attempts to fill this gap in the literature.
In this study, the central assumption is that the government does not simply maximize social welfare. That is, we assume that the public firm maximizes social welfare, and that the government emphasizes both social welfare and its preference for tax revenues (i.e., a policy defined as the government’s “tax-inclusive social welfare,” hereinafter called the government’s payoff. See also Section 2.). While the criterion for relative tax efficiency in the literature is a higher tax revenue for a given total output under fairly general conditions, in this study, the government needs to indirectly control the level of industry output to balance social welfare and its tax revenue policy. It does so by choosing between the specific and ad valorem taxes as the optimal type of taxes2.
In fact, the present study differs from the existing literature in at least two important ways. First, the existing studies on mixed oligopolies consider a monolithic entity that seeks to maximize social welfare at both the public firm and the government levels. Second, previous studies on unionized mixed oligopolies mainly focus on Cournot competition without tax effects, whereas our study investigates tax effects, and compares social welfare with the government’s payoff. Indeed, it also corresponds to the empirical results that in Europe, Japan, and the US, the government is strongly involved in the setting of public sector wages (Bordogna, 2003; Rose, 2004; Du Caju et al., 2008). From a recent empirical study, Bordogna (2003, pp. 62-63) pointed out that “even where bargaining has been decentralized, governments have often maintained strong, centralized, financial controls in order to contain public expenditures and avoid inflationary consequences of the decentralization process” (see also Brock and Lipsy (2003) and references therein). To investigate the optimal privatization policy, incorporating unions’ behavior into the different objectives of the government and the public firm can serve to explain the government’s use of taxes as a commitment device to control the unions’ wage demands. In general, a higher tax forces down both public and private firms’ wages since wages are strategic complements between the unions. As such, unions’ behavior is considered in this study.
The present study shows several results: Given that one of the tax regimes is predetermined, privatization never improves welfare and is preferable for the government when it emphasizes tax revenue. However, when the tax regime is endogenously determined by the government, privatization is preferable from the viewpoint of social welfare if the government heavily emphasizes tax revenue from ad valorem taxes. Thus, there are conflicts of interest between the public firm and the government. That is, if the government heavily emphasizes tax revenue, then the government always has an incentive to levy a specific tax, while the public firm has an incentive to be levied an ad valorem tax. However, there are no conflicts of interest between the public firm and the government when the latter levies a specific tax if the government’s preference for tax revenues is sufficiently small. Interestingly, the government never has an incentive for privatization when considering a choice of tax regimes between ad valorem and specific taxes.

2. Relationship with the Literature

In this section, we discuss the relationship between our study and some other previous theoretical or empirical studies on government’s preference for tax revenues, and closely follow Choi (2011).
We present some rationale for discussing objective functions from the perspective of government objectives. First, it has been argued in the literature that fiscal centralization increase the discretionary power of government when a Leviathan government exist. Therefore, the literature contains a number of puzzles for fiscal centralization and the size of the public sector (Oates, 1989). For example, Brennan and Buchanan (1980) formulated the hypothesis of a Leviathan government attempting to maximize revenue for its own private agenda3. A similar idea lies behind Niskanen’s (1971) model of a budget-maximizing bureau, although the bureau interacts with the government rather than with voters. This political power may fit with the analysis of the government4.
Second, the objective of the public firm is not the same as that of the government because the government may find it hard to control some public firms. The advantage of the public firm is that it allows the government to distance itself from public sector activities that create discontent. This reduction of political interference is widely perceived as an improvement in social efficiency. According to Vickers and Yarrow (1988), in the postwar period in the UK, a principal objective of the legislation that established public corporations was to create an “arm’s length” relationship between the government and management. Unsurprisingly, managers (of the public firms) and politicians took full advantage of the discretion allowed them (Vickers and Yarrow (1988)). As argued above, we can justify the viewpoint that the objective of the public firm is to promote social welfare, while that of the government is to secure both social welfare and attainment of tax revenues.
A recent study that comes closest to differentiating the government’s objective function is that by Kato (2008), who only focuses on the specific tax. Kato (2008) showed that the government’s choice of privatization of the public firm would depend on its preference for tax revenues if the following two assumptions hold true: First, the public firm fully emphasizes the social welfare net of tax revenues (which is defined as the sum of consumer and producer surpluses), and second, the government emphasizes both social welfare net of tax revenues and its preference for tax revenues. Rather than following Kato (2008) in ascribing the difference in objectives between the government and the public firm, Choi (2011) demonstrated that regardless of the government’s preference for tax revenues and the number of private firms, the government and the public firm do not always have an incentive for privatization without the choice of tax regimes. Considering that the specific tax involves a transfer within the economy, Choi’s (2011) assumption of the public firm differs from that of Kato (2008).

3. The Model

Consider a mixed-duopoly situation for a homogeneous good that is supplied by a public firm and a private firm. Firm 1 is a profit-maximizing private firm and Firm 0 is a public firm that maximizes social welfare. Assume that the inverse demand is characterized by where is the price of the good, is the output level of the public firm, and is the output level of the private firm.
On the demand side of the market, the representative consumer’s utility is a quadratic function given by
We assume that the public and private firms are unionized and that the firms are homogeneous with respect to productivity. Given that is the number of workers employed in the ith firm, each firm adopts a constant returns-to-scale technology, where one unit of labor produces one unit of the final good. The price of labor (i.e., wage) that firm has to pay is denoted by Let denote the reservation wage. Taking as given, the union’s optimal wage-setting strategy, regarding firm is defined as follows:
where is the weight that the union attaches to the wage level. Following Ishida and Matsushima (2009) in the literature on unionized mixed duopoly, we assume that and to demonstrate our results simply5. That is, the utility function of the union at the firm is its wage bill: Thus, we consider the monopoly union model, which assumes that the unions set the wage, while the firms choose the employment level once the wage is set by the unions (see also Booth, 1995).
In what follows, we assume that either an ad valorem tax or a specific tax rate is imposed on the public and private firms. To distinguish notations, the superscript “s” (respectively, “v”) is defined when the specific (respectively, ad valorem) tax is imposed on the public and private firms. In the case of an ad valorem tax, the producer price, for the good is obtained as where denotes the consumer price for the good. If a specific tax is imposed, the producer price is defined by Thus, introducing ad valorem taxation at the (tax inclusive) rate and a specific tax of each firm’s profit follows the function,
respectively. The profit expression is the same when taxes are set such that if the total output is fixed to be the same under the two taxes. However, as stated in the introduction, we do not consider this case since the government has preference for tax revenues to balance social welfare and the government’s tax revenues by choosing between the specific and ad valorem taxes as the optimal type of tax.
As usual, social welfare, can be defined as the sum of consumer surplus CS, producer surplus PS, the utilities of unions U, and total tax revenue collected by the government. Thus, the public firm aims to maximize social welfare, which is defined as
(1)
where and (respectively, ) denotes the tax revenues when the specific (respectively, ad valorem) tax is imposed on both firms. As tax revenues collected under each type of tax, is considered as a transfer within the economy.
Furthermore, we also assume that the government’s payoff, is given by
(2)
where is the parameter that represents the weight of the government’s preference for tax revenues, captures the cost of raising tax (i.e., the same weight is given to tax revenue and to the cost of raising tax)6 and is defined as net tax revenues. Here, the government values the tax revenues, more than social welfare, when Otherwise, the government values the tax revenues less than social welfare when . For the setup of different objectives, we introduce strict convexity of the cost function as an inefficiency of the government when it prefers tax revenues, in order to endogenize the inefficiency in collection and comparing ad valorem and specific taxes. This view of the government can be a focus for rent-seeking, in which the government is seen arguably as serving bureaucrats’ or politicians’ interests (e.g., Besley, 2006, chapter 1).
Finally, the timing of the game is as follows. In the first stage, the government chooses whether or not to privatize the public firm, and simultaneously determines either the specific tax or ad valorem tax rate on the public and private firms. In the second stage, union i chooses its wage, after being made aware of each type of tax rate. In the third stage, firm i chooses its output simultaneously to maximize its respective objective, considering the type of tax imposed by the government and the wage levels.

4. Results

Before comparisons of indirect taxation and market type with the government’s payoff and social welfare, two cases are distinguished between the unionized mixed and privatized duopolies7: (i) a specific tax rate is imposed; and (ii) the tax is fixed by an ad valorem tax rate. Thus, the game is solved by backward induction, that is, the solution concept used is the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium.

4.1. Unionized Mixed Duopoly

First, we consider the case of specific tax under unionized mixed duopoly. In this case, the public firm’s objective is to maximize social welfare, which is defined as the sum of consumer surplus, individual firms’ profits, unions’ utilities, and specific tax revenues. Thus, given and for each firm , the public firm’s maximization problem is as follows:
As shown in Ishida and Matsushima (2009), the constraint implies there is some lower-bound restriction on the public firm’s profit, that is, the public firm faces a budget constraint8.
If the multiplier of the budget constraint is denoted as the Lagrangian equation can be written as
(3)
Given the specific tax rate and the wage levels, by solving the first-order conditions (3), we obtain
(4)
(5)
On the other hand, the optimal output for a private firm is given by
(6)
Given these results, we now obtain the output level for each firm. By solving the first-order conditions, (4), (5), and (6), we obtain,
(7)
(8)
For solving the first-order conditions of the Lagrangian equation, the budget constraint is momentarily treated as binding. We check ex-post whether this omitted constraint is binding9.
In the second stage, the equilibrium wages, denoted as are obtained by maximizing In addition, the substitution of each optimal wage into (7) yields the respective equilibrium outputs, The equilibrium wages and outputs, and , respectively, can be obtained as follows:
(9)
We now move to the first stage of the game. From (9), the government’s payoff, in the mixed duopoly can be rewritten as
A straightforward computation yields the optimal tax rate as
(10)
If the weight of the government’s preference for tax revenues is sufficiently large, as in the case of the optimal specific tax rate becomes positive. Conversely, when it is small, as in the case of the optimal specific tax rate becomes negative10, and in the case of the optimal specific tax rate is zero. We find that the greater the weight of the government’s preference for tax revenues, the higher will be the specific tax rate imposed by the government. Thus, by using (10), we obtain the following result.
Lemma 1: Suppose that a specific tax rate is imposed on both public and private firms. Then, the equilibrium wages, output, union’s utilities, government’s payoff, social welfare, consumer surplus, and private firm’s profit levels under a unionized mixed duopoly are given by
From Lemma 1, it should be noted that the public firm would like to maximize by setting the output at the zero-profit level Usually, in the absence of unions’ wage-bargaining power and when the government would provide firms a subsidy to derive price down to the marginal cost. However, for the price would remain above the marginal cost, and a subsidy would encourage the unions to set higher wages. Therefore, a tax is required to be used to control the unions’ wage demands. By substituting Lemma 1 into (8), we obtain
which shows that the budget constraint is binding.
Second, we consider the case of ad valorem tax under unionized mixed duopoly. Given the ad valorem tax, and for each firm in the third stage, the public firm’s maximization problem is given as follows:
Denoting the multiplier of the budget constraint and repeating the same process as in the previous case yields the first-order conditions of the Lagrangian equation with respect to and with the optimal output for a private firm11.
(11)
(12)
In the second stage, given the output as a function of wage, each union at each firm sets the wage, that maximizes union rent, A straightforward computation yields the equilibrium wage and output. Repeating the same process as in previous cases yields the first-order conditions of the government’s payoff, That is, the optimal tax rate is given by . Thus, by using , we have the following result.
Lemma 2: Suppose that an ad valorem tax rate is imposed on both public and private firms. Then, the equilibrium wages, outputs, union’s utilities, government’s payoff, social welfare, consumer surplus, and private firm’s profit under a unionized mixed duopoly are given by
Lemma 2 suggests that each firm's wage, output, and union's utility does not depend on since the ad valorem tax rate affects only the government's payoff. By substituting Lemma 2 into (12), we obtain
which shows that the budget constraint is binding.

4.2. Unionized Privatized Duopoly

This subsection investigates the equilibrium of a unionized privatized duopoly in the case of indirect taxes. As discussed in the basic model, consider the situation of a unionized privatized duopoly for a homogeneous good that is supplied by a profit-maximizing private firm
First, we consider the case of specific tax under unionized privatized duopoly. In the third stage, given and the firm profit-maximization problem is to maximize where Hence, the symmetry across private firms implies that each firm’s output level is given by
(13)
In the second stage of this case, each firm’s wage level is set to maximize the firm’s union utility: Repeating the same process as in the previous subsection, straightforward computations and symmetry across private firms yield each firm’s wage and output:
(14)
Turning to the first stage and using the equilibrium outputs and wages, the government’s payoff, in a unionized privatized duopoly can be rewritten as
A straightforward computation yields the following optimal tax rate in the unionized privatized duopoly:
(15)
If the weight of the government preference for tax revenues is sufficiently large (as in the case when ) the optimal tax rate becomes positive. Conversely, when it is small (as in the case when ), the optimal tax rate becomes negative. Further, in the case when the optimal tax rate is zero. Similar to the previous subsection, we have the following result.
Lemma 3: Suppose that a specific tax rate is imposed on private firms. Then, the equilibrium wages, outputs, union’s utilities, government’s payoff, social welfare, consumer surplus, and private firm’s profit levels under a unionized privatized duopoly are given by
Similar to the previous case lemmas 3 and 4, we now analyze the case of the ad valorem tax in a unionized privatized duopoly. In the third stage, given and , the firm profit-maximization problem is to maximize where Hence, the symmetry across private firms implies that each output level is given by
(16)
In the second stage, given the output as a function of wage, each union at each firm sets the wage, that maximizes union rent, A straightforward computation yields the equilibrium wage and output. Repeating the same process as in the previous cases yields the first-order conditions of the government’s payoff, That is, the optimal tax rate is given by Thus, by using we can compute each equilibrium value as follows:
Lemma 4: Suppose that an ad valorem tax rate is imposed on private firms. Then, the equilibrium wages, outputs, union’s utilities, government’s payoff, social welfare, consumer surplus, and private firm’s profit under a unionized privatized duopoly are given by

5. Comparisons of Indirect Taxation and Market Type

Having derived the equilibrium for the two types of tax regimes in the previous section, we will determine either exogenously or endogenously the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium in the first stage. If the type of taxes is fixed, we can state the following results from easy comparisons of calculations that we can omit12:
Proposition 1: Suppose that the type of taxes is fixed under either mixed or privatized duopoly. Then, in the first stage,
(i) Moreover,
(ii) if ; otherwise, if
The intuition for Proposition 1(i) is as follows. When imposing specific tax, the price under a unionized mixed duopoly is always smaller than under a unionized privatized duopoly For this reason, the government uses tax as a commitment device to control the union’s wage demands to maintain lower wage levels under unionized mixed duopoly Thus, lower wages under the unionized mixed duopoly work to improve welfare by increasing the total output, thus raising the tax revenues. This leads to more output under a unionized mixed duopoly than under a unionized privatized duopoly. On the other hand, privatization under specific taxes leads to a reduction in total output and an increase in market price (i.e., and ). This implies that the private firm under the privatization obtains a higher profit and produces less total output since regardless of condition while
However, when imposing ad valorem tax with and , a higher ad valorem tax forces down both public and private firms’ wages since wages are strategic complements between the unions, while reducing the firms’ revenue. The latter effect dominates the former effect, which leads to greater reduction in total output and an increase in market price under a unionized privatized duopoly than those under a unionized mixed duopoly when imposing ad valorem tax. Hence, imposing ad valorem tax also works to decrease firms’ revenue, even though the government uses tax as a commitment device to control the union’s wage demands to maintain lower wage levels.
On the other hand, Proposition 1(ii) states that if the government levies ad valorem tax at the first stage, comparisons of the government’s payoff in the first stage can vary with Because and , an increase in the producer’s price requires a greater increase in the consumer price under privatized duopoly than under unionized mixed duopoly. This leads to increased ad valorem tax revenue if the government’s preference for tax revenue is sufficiently large. On the other hand, a decrease in consumer price reduces the net price received by each firm by less than the decrease in consumer price. This part of the cost is borne by the government, and will be smaller under a mixed duopoly. As a result, when the government levies an ad valorem tax, conflicts of interest with respect to privatization will always arise between the public firm and the government if its preference for tax revenues is sufficiently large. Proposition 1 differs from the results of Mujumdar and Pal (1998), which demonstrated that privatization can increase both social welfare and tax revenues. In contrast, our study shows that when the government and the public firm do not have the same objectives, privatization is not always desirable in terms of social welfare from the viewpoint of the public firm.
Moreover, we can state the following results when the type of markets is fixed.
Proposition 2: Suppose that the type of markets is fixed under either ad valorem or specific tax. Then, in the first stage,
(i) otherwise, if
(ii) otherwise, if
(iii) otherwise, if
(iv) otherwise, if
Proof: See the appendix for parts (i) and (ii). When comparing the government’s payoff, it can calculate simply. Q.E.D.
The intuition for Proposition 2 (i) is as follows. Consider the condition that In this case, the price under the imposition of the specific tax rate is smaller than that under that of the ad valorem tax rate13. However, because and , a higher ad valorem tax forces down both public and private firms’ wages, while reducing the firms’ revenue. The latter effect dominates the former effect, which leads to a greater reduction in total output (i.e., higher market price) when imposing ad valorem tax than that when imposing specific tax if and vice versa. This condition implies that the total output level under ad valorem tax is smaller than that under specific tax (i.e., if ). As a result, it turns out that social welfare under ad valorem tax is smaller than that under specific tax if However, if these effects are reversed. When comparing with , similar explanations are adopted by using the critical value of Note that we will mention the intuitions of Proposition 2 (iii) and (iv) later, because endogenous comparisons can exclude off the equilibrium paths.
Finally, we need to investigate endogenously the subgame perfect Nash equilibrium in the first stage. Since the government determines the choice variables (the type of taxes and markets) in the first stage, the government chooses the best choice from the four options of Section 4. However, we do not need to compare with and with since in Proposition 1 (i). This implies that at the stage of choosing the type of markets and taxes, we can exclude the case of the unionized privatized duopoly under specific tax. Moreover, considering the social welfare of the results of Propositions 1 and 2, we see the impact of the government's payoff at the stage of choosing the type of taxes when we recall that the “net” tax revenue under ad valorem tax is and that collected under specific tax is (let denote net tax revenue under privatization with each tax regime). Therefore, we can state the following results15.
Proposition 3: Suppose that the government prefers either specific or ad valorem tax revenue when it considers such type of markets as an option, and the assumption holds. Then, in the first stage,
(i) otherwise, if
(ii)
(iii) otherwise, if
(iv)
(v) otherwise, if
(vi)
The intuition for Proposition 3 (i) is as follows16. Consider the first case where the government’s preference for tax revenues is sufficiently small (i.e., in Proposition 3 (i)) under a mixed duopoly. In this case, due to the fact that and there is higher net tax revenue under ad valorem tax. Besides this direct effect, social welfare under specific tax is higher than that under ad valorem tax. We call the former the “net tax effect” and the latter the “welfare effect.” With Propositions 3 (i) and (iii), the government’s payoff improvement is possible when the welfare effect under specific tax dominates the net tax effect under ad valorem tax, once its preference for tax revenues is sufficiently small17. On the other hand, it is important to notice that in a mixed duopoly, the ad valorem tax rate is higher than the specific tax rate if the government’s preference for tax revenues is sufficiently large Due to the fact that owing to lower equilibrium output under specific tax, the implication is that as in Proposition 3 (i). However, the welfare effect under ad valorem tax is dominated by the net tax effect under specific tax as Proposition 3 (iii) states. In addition, if the government’s preference for tax revenues falls in the middle range, under a mixed duopoly, the government’s payoff under ad valorem tax is larger than that under specific tax since both welfare and net tax effects under ad valorem tax are always greater than under specific tax.
Finally, the intuition for Proposition 3 (ii) is as follows. The price under specific tax is higher than that under ad valorem tax since total output under specific tax is larger if In this case, due to the fact that , lowering output under specific tax in mixed duopoly, it turns out that as in Proposition 3 (vi). However, the welfare effect under ad valorem tax is dominated by the net tax effect under specific tax, as stated in Proposition 3 (iv). Therefore, we obtain Proposition 3 (ii).
Hence, noting either critical value, we compare the government’s payoff under both market competitions with both tax regimes. The graphs of comparisons of G are shown in Figure 1.
Figure 1. Comparisons of government payoff
In sum, Proposition 3 suggests that there are no conflicts of interest between the public firm and the government when the government levies a specific tax under unionized mixed duopoly if its preference for tax revenues is sufficiently small. This is because the government always prefers specific tax to ad valorem under unionized mixed duopoly, and However, if the government’s preference for tax revenues is sufficiently large, while the public firm has the incentive to be levied an ad valorem tax, the government always has an incentive to levy specific tax: and Interestingly, in line with Proposition 3, the government never has an incentive for privatization. Hence, Propositions 3 shows that depending on the government’s preference for tax revenues, the conflict between these two views of objective functions typically induces a conflict with regard to imposing either tax.

6. Concluding Remarks

This study investigated changes in social welfare and the government’s payoff on the basis of different objective functions of the government and the public firm. Specifically it compared the efficiency of ad valorem taxes with that of specific taxes in both a unionized mixed duopoly and privatization.
We found that the comparative effect on social welfare and government’s payoff is endogenously determined by welfare and net tax effects as follows: There are no conflicts of interest between the public firm and the government when the government levies a specific tax under unionized mixed duopoly if its preference for tax revenues is sufficiently small. However, if the government’s preference for tax revenues is sufficiently large, while the public firm has the incentive to be levied an ad valorem tax, the government always has an incentive to levy specific tax. Interestingly, the government never has an incentive for privatization. This means that the government doesn’t want to privatization compared to levy tex.
However, there remains much to be explored regarding the empirical impact of tax structure and asymmetric Bertrand competition with unionized mixed oligopoly. Moreover, there could be important economic implications if the analysis is expanded to include the entry of private firms and varying motives for bargaining among firms in the existing framework of mixed oligopolistic markets. The extension of our model in these directions remains an agendum for future research.

Appendix: Proofs

Proof of Proposition 1
(i): Comparing with yields , and comparing with yields Moreover, comparing with yields
(ii): Comparing with yields
if otherwise
Proof of Proposition 2
Since in Proposition 1, is excluded by choosing when comparing social welfare.
(i): Comparing with , and with yields and and By applying to a discriminant and ignoring the nonpositive roots for through the assumption, we have the root and Since the maximum value is attained from (respectively, ), (respectively, if (respectively, ); otherwise, (respectively, ) if (respectively, ).
Proof of Proposition 3
Since in Proposition 1, is excluded by choosing when comparing government’s payoff. Moreover, when comparing with the parameter of the government’s preference for tax revenues needs to start from because of Proposition 1(ii). Otherwise, the government will choose rather than Also, if in the range of from Proposition 1(ii), it should compare with
(i) and (ii): Comparing with and with yield
if
Otherwise, if
Other ways of straightforward calculations of Proposition 3 are shown in Table A-1. Using numerical examples to illustrate the impact of straightforward computations yield as follows.
Table A-1. Numerical Examples
     
(iii) and (iv): Comparing with and with yield
otherwise
otherwise
respectively. However, when comparing the government’s payoff in the case of mixed duopoly and specific tax and that under the case of privatization and ad valorem tax, the parameter of the government’s preference for tax revenues needs to begin from because of Proposition 1(ii). Otherwise, the government will choose Thus, when the net tax revenue under the case of privatization and ad valorem tax is always smaller than that under the case of a mixed duopoly and specific tax.
(iv): Comparing with yields

Notes

1. Two exceptions are Anant et al. (1995) and Pal and Sharma (2013). The former study showed how to model government-firm interactions and serves as a guide for other models, by adopting the revenue-maximization assumption of the government with a monopoly firm and relaxing key assumptions of the models. The latter study considered a linear combination of net tax revenue and social welfare to endogenize the objective function of governments in a model of tax competition. In this study, we use the non-linear, rather than the linear, combination for the analysis. To the best of our knowledge, such an attempt has not been made in the relevant literature.
2. In a setting, where the specific tax is adjusted to ensure that both specific and ad valorem taxes lead to the same level of industry output, there exists an ad valorem tax that yields the same social welfare with higher tax revenue for the government as any given specific tax. Under this setting, as in the literature, even if the government emphasizes both social welfare and its preference for tax revenues, there are no conflicts of interest between the public firm and the government. This irrelevant case is excluded in the present study.
3. In theoretical studies of the Leviathan government, Edwards and Keen (1996) and Rauscher (2000) used formalized tax-competition models to address the issue and showed that the results of tax competition are ambiguous. For more detailed treatment of the Leviathan government, recent theoretical and empirical studies include Oates (1989), Keen and Kotsogiannis (2002), and Brulhart and Jametti (2006).
4. According to Persson and Tabellini (2002, p. 7), the government raises taxes and spends the resulting revenue on three items: (1) general public goods; (2) narrowly targeted redistribution to well-defined groups; and (3) rents for politicians.
5. As Ishida and Matsushima (2009), Barcena-Ruiz and Garzon (2009), Horrn and Wolinsky (1988), and Haucap and Wey (2004) have suggested, this is because wage claims are decided by the elasticity of labor demand rather than the firm’s profit, as a special case of Nash bargaining solution, the monopoly union model (Oswald, 1982) is frequently adopted. Even if the present model of union's utility loses generality, the wage bill maximization enables us to gain insights; otherwise, it complicates the comparison between a specific tax with an ad valorem tax under either privatization or mixed duopoly.
6. If this cost is not allowed, the government’s payoff can indefinitely raise its ad valorem tax rate because the optimal ad valorem tax level of the government is independent of the government’s preference for tax revenues. Moreover, the cost-raising feature can be interpreted as the political cost of raising tax (e.g., perks or lobby cost) or X-inefficiency within the government (see, for example, Leibenstein, 1987). More clear extensions and government’s cost analysis of depending on total output are left to future research to develop the analysis more generally. Another possible way to solve this problem is to interpret the taxes collected by the government as Parameter represents the percentage of taxes paid by firms that goes to the government; the remaining percent represents the social cost of collecting the taxes (e.g., bureaucracy). Taking into account this assumption, social welfare is defined as and the government’s payoff can be defined as In general, incorporating into a transfer within the economy makes the effect on social welfare and government’s payoff complicated.
7. We will discuss indirect taxation models assuming that the government chooses either mixed duopoly or privatization. Later, we will mention this why we use the fixed decision.
8. In this model, if the public firm does not face the budget constraint, the public firm’s union can indefinitely raise its wage level because the optimal output level of the public firm is independent of the wage level.
9. Some readers may argue that the budget constraint may be non-binding on off-equilibrium paths. Kuhn-Tucker conditions regarding off-equilibrium paths for any values of are available from the author upon request. To provide correct calculations, we present Supplementary Material, which is only available for the reviewers and editor.
10. This implies that the government needs to intervene by considering a subsidy, such as a production subsidy. In reality, governments often directly provide subsidies to many sectors, including medical care, energy, finance, and international trade. According to Tomaru and Saito (2010, p. 42), “in Japan, the Small and Medium Enterprise Agency provides private firms with subsidies in order to encourage distribution services and enhance their efficiency. Yamato Transport, which is one of the major delivery enterprisers and competes against Japan Post which is a semi-public firm, is subsidized.” Thus, studies on optimal subsidy in mixed oligopolies have gained prominence in recent years (e.g., White, 1996; Tomaru and Saito, 2010; Tomaru and Kiyono, 2010).
11. To solve the Lagrangian equation, suppose that the budget constraint is momentarily binding. We check ex-post that this constraint is binding.
12. To provide correct calculations, we present Supplementary Material, which is only available for the reviewers and editor.
13. Thus, comparing each consumer surplus depends on if
14. By comparing with we get if otherwise, if
15. Since a comparison of the government’s payoff and net tax revenue is easily possible from direct calculations (i.e., Proposition 3 (i)-(vi)), which are available from the author upon request. Moreover, when comparing with the parameter of the government’s preference for tax revenues needs to begin from because of Proposition 1(ii). Otherwise, the government will choose rather than Also, if in the range of from Proposition 1(ii), it should compare with
16. The intuition for Proposition 3 (v) and (vi) is already explained in Proposition 2. Hence, as stated in the intuition for Proposition 2 (i), when comparing with we get
17. Strictly speaking, in the case of where the government’s payoff under ad valorem tax is larger than that under specific tax, since both welfare and net tax effects under ad valorem taxes are always greater than those under specific taxes.

References

[1]  Anant, T., K. Basu, and B. Mukherji, 1995, “A Model of Monopoly with Strategic Government Intervention,” Journal of Public Economic, 57, 25-43.
[2]  Barcena-Ruiz, J. C. and M. B. Garzon, 2009, “Relocation and Public Ownership of Firms,” Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 23, 71-85.
[3]  Besley, T., 2006, Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government, Oxford University Press.
[4]  Booth, A., 1995, The Economics of the Trade Union, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
[5]  Bordogna, L., 2003, “The Reform of Public Firm Employment Relations in Industrialized Democracy,” In Brock, J. and Lipsy, D. B. (eds), Going Public: The Role of Labor-Management Relations in Delivering Quality Government Services, Industrial Relations Research Association Series, pp. 23-67.
[6]  Brennan, G. and J. Buchanan, 1980, The Power to Tax: Analytical Foundations of a Fiscal Constitution, Cambridge University Press.
[7]  Brulhart, M. and M. Jametti, 2006, “Vertical versus Horizontal Tax Externalities: An Empirical Test,” Journal of Public Economics, 90, 2027-2062.
[8]  Caplan, B. 2001, “Has Leviathan been Bound? A Theory of Imperfectly Constrained Government with Evidence from the States,” Southern Economic Journal, 67, 825-847.
[9]  Choi, K., 2011, “Unions, Government’s Preference, and Privatization,” Economic Modelling, 28, 2502-2508.
[10]  Delipalla, S. and M. Keen, 1992, “The Comparison between Ad Valorem and Specific Taxation under Imperfect Competition,” Journal of Public Economics, 49, 351-367.
[11]  Du Caju, P., E. Gautier, D. Momferatou and M. Ward-Warmedinger, 2008, “Institutional Features of Wage Bargaining in 23 European Countries, the US and Japan,” Working Paper, NERE 228, Banque de France.
[12]  Edwards, J. and M. Keen, 1996, “Tax Competition and Leviathan,” European Economic Review, 40, 113-140.
[13]  Horn, H. and A. Wolinsky, 1988, “Bilateral Monopolies and Incentives for Merger,” Rand Journal of Economic, 19, 408-419.
[14]  Ishida, J. and N. Matsushima, 2009, “Should Civil Servants be Restricted in Wage Bargaining? A Mixed-Duopoly Approach,” Journal of Public Economics, 93, 634-646.
[15]  Leibenstein, H. 1987, Inside the Firm: The Inefficiencies of Hierarchy, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA.
[16]  Mujumdar, S. and D. Pal, 1998, “Effects of Indirect Taxation in a Mixed Oligopoly,” Economics Letters, 58, 199-204.
[17]  Niskanen, W. A., 1971, Bureaucracy and Representative Government, New York: Aldine-Ahterton.
[18]  Oates, W. E., 1989, “Searching for Leviathan: A Reply and Some Further Reflection,” American Economic Review, 79, 578-583.
[19]  Oswald, A. J., 1982, “The Microeconomic Theory of Trade Unions,” Economic Journal, 367, 576-595.
[20]  Pal, R. and A. Sharma, 2013, “Endogenizing Governments' Objectives in Tax Competition,” Regional Science and Urban Economics, 43, 570-578.
[21]  Persson, T. and G. Tabellini, 2002, Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy, MIT Press.
[22]  Rauscher, M., 2000, “Interjurisdictional Competition and Public-sector Prodigality: The Triumph of the Market over the State? ” Finanzarchiv, 57, 89-105.
[23]  Seade, J. 1985, “Profitable Cost Increases and the Shifting of Taxation: Equilibrium Responses of Markets in Oligopoly,” Working Paper, No. 260, University of Warwick.
[24]  Tomaru, Y. and K. Kiyono, 2010, “Endogenous Timing in Mixed Duopoly with Increasing Marginal Costs,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, 166, 591-613.
[25]  Tomaru, Y. and M. Saito, 2010, “Mixed Duopoly, Privatization and Subsidization in an Endogenous Timing Framework,” Manchester School, 78, 41-59.
[26]  Vickers, J. and G. Yarrow, 1988, Privatization: An Economic Analysis, MIT Press, Cambridge.
[27]  White, M. D. 1996, “Mixed Oligopoly, Privatization and Subsidization,” Economics Letters, 53, 189-195.
[28]  Zax, J. S. 1989, “Is There a Leviathan in Your Neighborhood?" American Economic Review, 79, 560-567.