Aika Monden
Graduate School of Business Administration, Kobe University, Kobe, Japan
Correspondence to: Aika Monden, Graduate School of Business Administration, Kobe University, Kobe, Japan.
Email: |  |
Copyright © 2017 Scientific & Academic Publishing. All Rights Reserved.
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY).
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Abstract
We compare equilibrium welfares under Cournot, Bertrand, and supply function competitions. Although it is a natural result that equilibrium outcomes under the supply function competition are intermediate between those under Cournot and Bertrand competitions, we show that the supply function competition may yield the smallest social welfare. To obtain this result, we consider a vertical market where an upstream firm sequentially contracts with two downstream firms.
Keywords:
Supply function competition, Price discrimination, Sequential contracting
Cite this paper: Aika Monden, Worst Welfare under Supply Function Competition with Sequential Contracting in a Vertical Relationship, Journal of Game Theory, Vol. 6 No. 2, 2017, pp. 38-42. doi: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170602.02.
1. Introduction
Fierce competition generally brings down price and raises social welfare. Recognizing this, antitrust authorities implement competition policies to intensify market competition. An index that can measure the competition intensity is the type of competition, that is, whether Cournot or Bertrand competition prevails. Previous studies focus on other indicators such as the number of firms and the degree of product differentiation, but regardless of the indicator is employed, tougher competition is desirable for society. Thus, several papers focus on a situation where equilibrium social welfare decreases with the competition intensity (Lahiri and Ono, 1988; Mukherjee and Zhao, 2009; Fanti, 2013). Thus, the literature on industrial organization compares outcomes under Cournot competition with those under Bertrand competition and finds that in many cases, Bertrand competition yields outcomes that are more desirable for society.For example, a classic study that compares Cournot competition with Bertrand competition is by Singh and Vives (1984). They show that the equilibrium price in Bertrand competition is lower than that in Cournot competition. Studies that followed indicate that this relationship is reversed (e.g., Delbono and Lambertin, 2016a; Häckner, 2000; Zanchettin, 2006).Some recent studies consider an intermediate competition type between Cournot and Bertrand competitions. One of them is supply function competition (Grossman, 1981; Klemperer and Meyer, 1989). Some recent studies analyze properties of supply function competitions (e.g., Delgado and Moreno, 2004; Ciarreta and Gutierrez-Hita, 2006; Menezes and Quiggin, 2012; Delbono and Lambertini, 2015, 2016b). Under the supply function competition, it is common wisdom that the supply function equilibrium is intermediate between that under Cournot and Bertrand (Delbono and Lambertini, 2015). However, Delbono and Lambertini (2016b) challenge this well-known result. They consider a market with quadratic cost and show that the supply function competition creates the largest social welfare among the competitions.Following Delbono and Lambertini (2016b), we reconsider a welfare ranking between Cournot, Bertrand, and the supply function competitions. There are some differences between our model and theirs. In particular, we consider a vertically related market where an upstream firm sequentially contracts with two downstream firms. Our formulation of a sequential contract is the same as that of Kim and Sim (2015). In other words, we introduce the supply function competition into the model with the sequential contract presented by Kim and Sim (2015).Because the supply function competition leads to Cournot and Bertrand equilibria as special cases, considering a supply function competition model suffices to examine whether Bertrand is the best outcome and Cournot, the worst. When comparing the two competition structures with other cases in the supply function competition, we show that Cournot and Bertrand competitions do not lead to the worst outcomes. That is, at parameter values where equilibrium outcomes are not the same as those under Cournot and Bertrand competitions, we obtain the minimum social welfare. This result is quite different from that in Delbono and Lambertini (2016b).The paper proceeds as follows. The next section presents the model. Section 3 calculates the equilibrium and provides the main results. Section 4 concludes the paper.
2. The Model
We consider a market with upstream firm
and two asymmetric downstream firms
To produce one unit of product, each downstream firm must purchase one unit of input from the upstream firm. We assume that the upstream firm can choose different prices for the downstream firms. We denote the wholesale price for downstream firm
by
Let
denote the output of downstream firm
We assume that the marginal cost of upstream firm
is zero, that of downstream firm
is also zero, and that of downstream firm
is
Following the literature on supply function competition, we assume that downstream firm
uses a linear supply function
, where
is the price, intercept
is an endogenous variable chosen by each firm, and
is an exogenous parameter.Menezes and Quiggin (2012) and Delbono and Lambertini (2015) show that as
converges to zero, equilibrium outcomes under the supply function competition converge to those under Cournot competition; however, as
diverges to infinity, equilibrium outcomes converge to those under Bertrand competition. Therefore, to compare equilibria under Cournot, Bertrand, and the supply function competitions, it suffices to consider the supply function competition with
Moreover, as an increase in
moves equilibrium outcomes closer to those in Bertrand competition, we can interpret
as the index of competition intensity. As downstream firm
is relatively inefficient, for large
the equilibrium output of
would take a value of zero. To guarantee a positive outcome, we assume
We assume that the inverse demand function is
As we assume a linear supply function, substituting
into the inverse demand function and solving it for
we have
Substituting this equation into
we have the following supply functions:
Using the above equations, we define the profits of downstream and upstream firms as follows:

Consumer surplus
and social welfare
Following Kim and Sim (2015), we consider the sequential contracts between the upstream and downstream firms. In the first stage, the upstream firm decides wholesale price
and in the second stage, downstream firm
chooses
in its supply function. After these decisions, in the third stage, the upstream firm offers wholesale price
and in the fourth stage, downstream firm
determines
in its supply function. We could justify this timing of the game as follows. When the upstream firm already creates a long-term relationship with downstream firm
the contract may express a commitment effect. Then, given the contract with downstream firm
the upstream firm and downstream firm
must negotiate their contract. Hence, a Stackelberg timing structure is a natural assumption here.We assume complete information. The model is solved by backward induction. Only pure strategies are considered throughout this paper.
3. Calculating Equilibrium and Condition Yielding Worst Welfare
The profit maximization problem of downstream firm
is
The first-order condition
yields
where superscript
represents that the outcomes are in stage 4. Substituting this outcome into
and
we have
and
Substituting the above results into the profit of the upstream firm, the maximization problem is
The first-order condition
leads to
where superscript
represents that the outcomes are in stage 3. Substituting this outcome into
and
we have
and
Substituting the above results into the profit of downstream firm
the maximization problem is
From the first-order condition
we have
where superscript
represents that the outcomes are in stage 2. Substituting this outcome into 
and
we have 
and 
Substituting the above outcomes into the profit of upstream firm, the maximization problem is
The first-order condition
leads to
where superscript
represents that the outcomes are in equilibrium. Summarizing the above results, we obtain the following proposition:Proposition 1. The equilibrium social welfare is
Where

Differentiating
with respect to
we have
where 


and
After a tedious calculation, we obtain the following proposition:Proposition 2. When we can freely choose a value of
the equilibrium social welfare is minimized at the following 
such that
satisfies
and
satisfies
where
Proof. First, using the discriminant of the numerator for
we show that the value of
that minimizes
does not exist in
As the sign of denominator is positive, the sign of first derivative is the same as that of numerator. The numerator is the quadratic function of
and the coefficient of
is positive
Then, if the sign of discriminant
is non-positive, we will have
Numerically solving
for
we have
Hence, the value of
that minimizes
does not exist in
Next, we consider the case with
We will show that the equilibrium social welfare increases with
if
or
As the discriminant takes a positive value, we have two solutions:
and
which satisfy
Solving
for
we have
Then, if
we have
Here, from numerical calculation, we show that 
and
This result implies that the maximum value of
such that 
at some
is derived from
and the minimum value of
such that
at some
is obtained from
. That is, 
and 
Hence, if
or
then the social welfare is minimized at
Finally, we consider the case with
From numerical calculation, we have
Hence,
is a strictly convex function of
Then, the first-order condition
characterizes the value
that minimizes
That is, by solving the first-order condition for
we have
and
From the discriminant
we have
Then, given the value of
that minimizes equilibrium social welfare is implicitly determined as follows:
where
satisfies
and
satisfies
Therefore, we obtain the proposition.We can depict the result of Proposition 2 in Figure 1. In this figure, there are three regions. In the right area, as we have
we omit this parameter range; in the shadow area, we have
in the bottom area, we have 
Hence, given
the boundary between the shadow and bottom areas determines
that leads to the minimum social welfare. | Figure 1. Effect of  |
This proposition means that if
is in the range
, the equilibrium social welfare is minimized neither at
nor for
In other words, under the supply function competition except where
and
the equilibrium social welfare is smaller than those under Cournot and Bertrand competitions. Now, we explain an intuition behind Proposition 2. Since we consider the case of a sequential contract, follower
faces a residual demand after leader
decides its output. Thus, the follower behaves less aggressively than in the case with a simultaneous contract. Then, to encourage the follower’s production, the upstream firm reduces the wholesale price for follower
As leader
knows this action, it reduces its own output. If a decrease in
output dominates an increase in
output, the total output reduces. Since in this case, an increase in
reduces social welfare and in the other case, the rise of
decreases the social welfare, there exists a positive
such that social welfare is minimized.
4. Conclusions
We consider the supply function competition structure in a vertical market with a sequential contract. We show that if the technological difference between downstream firms is moderate, an intermediate competition intensity yields the minimum social welfare. This result indicates that a competition policy that enhances competition, measured by the type of competition, is not desirable for society.
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
I would like to express my cordial gratitude to Tomomichi Mizuno for his sincere encouragement, constructive and helpful comments, and in-depth discussion during the various stages of preparation. Needless to say, all remaining errors are mine.
References
[1] | Ciarreta, A. and Gutiérrez-Hita, C. (2006) “Supply function vs. quantity competition in supergames” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 24(4), 773-783. |
[2] | Delbono, F. and Lambertini, L. (2016a) “Bertrand versus Cournot with convex variable costs” Economic Theory Bulletin, 4(1), 73-83. |
[3] | Delbono, F. and Lambertini, L. (2015) “On the properties of linear supply functions in oligopoly” Economics Letters, 136, 22-24. |
[4] | Delbono, F. and Lambertini, L. (2016b) “Ranking Bertrand, Cournot and supply function equilibria in oligopoly” Energy Economics, 60, 73-78. |
[5] | Delgado, J. and Moreno, D. (2004) “Coalition-proof supply function equilibria in oligopoly” Journal of Economic Theory, 114(2), 231-254. |
[6] | Fanti, L. (2013) “Cross-ownership and unions in a Cournot duopoly: When profits reduce with horizontal product differentiation” Japan and the World Economy, 27, 34-40. |
[7] | Grossman, S.J. (1981) “Nash equilibrium and the industrial organization of markets with large fixed costs” Econometrica, 49(5), 1149-1172. |
[8] | Häckner, J. (2000) “A note on price and quantity competition in differentiated oligopolies” Journal of Economic Theory, 93(2), 233-239. |
[9] | Kim, H. and Sim, S.G. (2015) “Price discrimination and sequential contracting in monopolistic input markets” Economics Letters, 128, 39-42. |
[10] | Klemperer, P.D. and Meyer, M.A. (1989) “Supply function equilibria in oligopoly under uncertainty” Econometrica, 57(6), 1243-1277. |
[11] | Lahiri, S. and Ono, Y. (1988) “Helping minor firms reduces welfare” The Economic Journal, 98(393), 1199-1202. |
[12] | Menezes, F.M. and Quiggin, J. (2012) “More competitors or more competition? Market concentration and the intensity of competition” Economics Letters, 117(3), 712-714. |
[13] | Mukherjee, A. and Zhao, L. (2009) “Profit raising entry” Journal of Industrial Economics, 57(4), 870. |
[14] | Singh, N. and Vives, X. (1984) “Price and quantity competition in a differentiated duopoly” RAND Journal of Economics, 15(4), 546-554. |
[15] | Zanchettin, P. (2006) “Differentiated duopoly with asymmetric costs” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 15(4), 999-1015. |