[1] | Wright, J. R. (2015). Behavioural Game Theory: Predictive Models and Mechanisms. In Advances in Artificial Intelligence (pp. 356-359). Springer International Publishing. |
[2] | Von Neumann, J., & Morgenstern, O. (1944). Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton University Press: Princeton, USA. |
[3] | Camerer, C. F., Ho, T. H., & Chong, J. K. (2004a). Behavioural Game Theory: Thinking, Learning and Teaching. In Advances in Understanding Strategic Behaviour (pp. 120-180). Palgrave Macmillan UK. |
[4] | Maschler, M., Solan, E., & Zamir, S. (2012). Game Theory. Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, UK. |
[5] | Chatain, O. (2014). Cooperative and non-cooperative game theory. In M. Augier and D. J. Teece (Eds.), The Palgrave Encyclopedia of Strategic Management. |
[6] | Brandenburger, A. M., & Nalebuff, B. J. (1995). The right game: Use game theory to shape strategy. Harvard Business Review, 73(4), 57-71. |
[7] | Xefteris, D. (2015). Symmetric zero-sum games with only asymmetric equilibria. Games and Economic Behavior, 89(C), 122-125. |
[8] | Nash, J. (1951). Non-cooperative games. Annals of mathematics, 286-295. |
[9] | Spangler, B. (2003). Positive-Sum, Zero-Sum, and Negative-Sum Situations. Beyond Intractability. Eds. Guy Burgess and Heidi Burgess. Conflict Information Consortium, University of Colorado, Boulder. Posted: October 2003, available at http://www.beyondintractability.org/essay/sum. |
[10] | Fama, E. F., & French, K. R. (2009). Why active investing is a negative sum game. Retrieved from https://www.dimensional.com/famafrench/essays/why-active-investing-is-a-negative-sum-game.aspx. |
[11] | Verbeek, B., & Morris, C. (2010). Game theory and ethics. The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy (Summer 2010 Edition), Edward N. Zalta (Ed.). Retrieved from http://plato.stanford.edu/archives/sum2010/entries/game-ethics/. |
[12] | Yildiz, M. (2012). 14.12 Economic Applications of Game Theory, Fall 2012. Massachusetts Institute of Technology: MIT OpenCourseWare, Retrieved from http://ocw.mit.edu. License: Creative Commons BYNCSA. |
[13] | Harsanyi, J. C. (1967). Games with incomplete information played by Bayesian players, I-III. Part I. The basic model. Management science, 14(3), 159-182. |
[14] | Lindstädt, H., & Müller, J. (2010). Making game theory work for managers. McKinsey Quarterly, 1-9. |
[15] | Camerer, C. F. (2003a). Behavioral game theory: Experiments in strategic interaction. Princeton University Press: Princeton, NJ. |
[16] | Plott, C. & V. Smith. (2008). Handbook of Experimental Economics Results. Elsevier: Amsterdam, Netherlands. |
[17] | Vailati, E. (2016). Behavioral Game Theory. Southern Illinois University. Retrieved from http://www.siue.edu/~evailat/gt-behavior.htm. |
[18] | Batson, C. D., Van Lange, P. A. M., Ahmad, N., & Lishner, D. A. (2007). Altruism and helping behavior. In M. A. Hogg and J. Cooper (Eds.), Sage handbook of social psychology (pp. 279-295). Sage Publications: London, UK. |
[19] | Lucas, G. M., McCubbins, M. D., & Turner, M. B. (2013). Can We Build Behavioral Game Theory?. Available at SSRN 2278029. |
[20] | Crawford, V. P. (2013). Introduction to behavioural game theory and game experiments. University of Oxford, Michaelmas Term 2013. Retrieved from http://econweb.ucsd.edu/~vcrawfor/BGTIntroductionSlides13.pdf. |
[21] | Falk, A., & Heckman, J. J. (2009). Lab experiments are a major source of knowledge in the social sciences. Science, 326(5952), 535-538. |
[22] | Camerer, C. F. (2003b). Behavioural studies of strategic thinking in games. Trends in Cognitive Science, 7(5), 225-231. |
[23] | Camerer, C. F. & Ho, T. H. (2015), Behavioral Game Theory Experiments and Modeling, Ch. 10. In Handbook of Game Theory with Economic Applications, vol. 4 (pp. 517-573). Elsevier. |
[24] | Camerer, C. F., Ho, T. H., & Chong, J. K. (2004b). A Cognitive Hierarchy Model of Games. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119(3), 861-898. |
[25] | Shah, A. K., & Oppenheimer, D. M. (2008). Heuristics made easy: an effort-reduction framework. Psychological Bulletin, 134(2), 207. |
[26] | Gill, D. & Prowse, V. (2012). Cognitive Ability and Learning to Play Equilibrium: A Level-k Analysis. Munich Personal RePEc Archive, Paper No. 38317, posted 23 April 2012. http://mpra.ub.uni-muenchen.de/38317/. |
[27] | Costa‐Gomes, M., Crawford, V. P., & Broseta, B. (2001). Cognition and behavior in normal‐form games: An experimental study. Econometrica, 69(5), 1193-1235. |
[28] | Kahneman, D. (1988). Experimental economics: A psychological perspective. In Bounded rational behavior in experimental games and markets (pp. 11-18). Springer: Berlin Heidelberg. |
[29] | Crawford, V. P. & Iriberri, N. (2007). Fatal attraction: Salience, naivete, and sophistication in experimental “hide-and-seek” games. The American Economic Review, 97(5), 1731-1750. |
[30] | Östling, R., Wang, J. T. Y., Chou, E. Y., & Camerer, C. F. (2011). Testing game theory in the field: Swedish LUPI lottery games. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 3(3), 1-33. |
[31] | Brown, A. L., Camerer, C. F., & Lovallo, D. (2013). Estimating structural models of equilibrium and cognitive hierarchy thinking in the field: The case of withheld movie critic reviews. Management Science, 59(3), 733-747. |
[32] | Crawford, V. P., Costa-Gomes, M. A., & Iriberri, N. (2010). Strategic thinking. Working Manuscript. University of Aberdeen Business School: Aberdeen, UK. |
[33] | McKelvey, R. & Palfrey, T. (1995). Quantal Response Equilibria for Normal Form Games. Games and Economic Behavior, 10(1), 6-38. |
[34] | Goeree, J. K., Holt, C. A., & Palfrey, T. R. (2010). Quantal response equilibria. In Behavioural and Experimental Economics (pp. 234-242). Palgrave Macmillan UK. |
[35] | Wright, J. R., & Leyton-Brown, K. (2012). Evaluating, Understanding, and Improving Behavioral Game Theory Models For Predicting Human Behavior in Unrepeated Normal-Form Games. Working paper, the University of British Columbia. |
[36] | Wright, J. R., & Leyton-Brown, K. (2010). Beyond Equilibrium: Predicting Human Behavior in Normal-Form Games. In Twenty-Fourth Conference of the Association for the Advancement of Artificial Intelligence, 901-907. |
[37] | Shu-Heng, C., & Ye-Rong, D. (2014). Heterogeneity in experienced-weighted attraction learning and its relation to cognitive ability. Neuropsychoeconomics Conference Proceedings, 22. |
[38] | Carpenter, J., Graham, M., & Wolf, J. (2013). Cognitive ability and strategic sophistication. Games and Economic Behavior, 80(C), 115-130. |
[39] | Yamagishi, T., Mifune, N., Li, Y., Shinada, M., Hashimoto, H., Horita, Y., ... & Takagishi, H. (2013). Is behavioral pro-sociality game-specific? Pro-social preference and expectations of pro-sociality. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 120(2), 260-271. |
[40] | Camerer, C. F., Ho, T. H., & Chong, J. K. (2015). A psychological approach to strategic thinking in games. Current Opinion in Behavioral Sciences, 3, 157-162. |
[41] | Gillen, B. J. (2009). Identification and estimation of level-k auctions. Available at SSRN 1337843. |
[42] | Goldfarb, A., & Xiao, M. (2011). Who thinks about the competition? Managerial ability and strategic entry in US local telephone markets. The American Economic Review, 101(7), 3130-3161. |