Yigal Gerchak
Department of Industrial Engineering, Tel-Aviv University, Israel
Correspondence to: Yigal Gerchak, Department of Industrial Engineering, Tel-Aviv University, Israel.
Email: |  |
Copyright © 2017 Scientific & Academic Publishing. All Rights Reserved.
This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY).
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Abstract
We consider two extensions of Bertrand's celebrated duopoly and tri-opoly models of differentiated products. One extension consists of generalizing linear production costs to convex ones. For quadratic costs, we obtain the symmetric equilibrium explicitly. The other is a two-period model where the demand in the second period depends on the price in the first period (reference price) as well. We obtain an explicit solution to the second period problem and characterize the optimal first period price.
Keywords:
Bertrand, Non-Linear Costs, Reference Prices
Cite this paper: Yigal Gerchak, Extensions of Bertrand's Differentiated Products Model, Journal of Game Theory, Vol. 6 No. 1, 2017, pp. 1-6. doi: 10.5923/j.jgt.20170601.01.
1. Introduction
Bertrand's model is one of the classical models of differentiated duopoly and is a forerunner of the Nash equilibrium. In this model demand for each firm increases in the competitor's price while decreasing in its own price [1-3]. In this classical model production costs are usually assumed to be linear. As such is often not the case, (e.g. [4, 5]), we explore duopoly and tri-opoly [6] scenarios with increasing marginal production costs. We also consider a two-period model where a firm's demand in the second period depends on its and its competitors’ price in the first period ("reference price"), as well on the second period prices [7, 8]. While such consumer behavior may not be entirely rational, there is ample empirical evidence in the marketing and psychology literature for its prevalence.For completeness, we first sketch the well-known Bertrand's linear duopoly model of differentiated products [2, 9] and then do so for a tri-opoly (cf. [6, 10]) and we include comparative statics. We show conditions under which a tri-opolist would charge a higher price than a duopolist. We then generalize them to non-linear production costs, where we focus on the case of quadratic costs for which we obtain an explicit solution. Finally, we consider a two-period duopoly with reference prices.
2. The Basic Model
The basic Bertrand duopoly model of differentiated products is
where
and where
and
are, respectively, the prices set by duopolists i and j, and
the resulting demand of duopolist i (e.g. [2, 9]).
is the cross effect of
on
.
is the quantity demanded when prices are zero. Thus this quantity is between
and
.
are assumed to be identical for both duopolists, so the model is symmetric. Now,
is positive if
and
or if
and
. Note that
profit is
where
is the unit production cost, and
.
, so
is concave in
.Here the Nash-equilibrium is the solution of
The symmetric solution
is thus
, which increases in
and
and decreases in
. (Note that since for a monopolist with this parametrization
, therefore 
, which increases in
, decreases in
and increases in
if 
, which increases in
and decreases in
and
; all are intuitive.For example, if
and 
3. Three Firms
Here the assumption is that
so the effect of other products’ prices on the demand of a product is symmetric (cf. [6]). So
Denoting
by
, we have 
The optimality condition implies that
So the symmetric solution is
and thus
which increases in
,
.
which increases in
and decreases in 
Here are some relevant comparative statics.
4. Non-Linear Costs Duopoly
Here
are the possibly, non-linear costs of duopolist
producing
units, with
and
thus 
To obtain an explicit solution we need a specific (family of) function(s) C.Example
so
Thus
so
i.e.,
For the symmetric solution 
so we have:Proposition 1 For quadratic costs
, which increases in
and
.
if
or
.Under this condition 
, which increases in
and decreases in
. It decreases in
if
. Under this condition 
i.e.,
It is possible to demonstrate that if
then
.
5. With Reference Price(s)
See Güler et al. [8] and Popescu and Wu [7] for suggestions for incorporating reference prices in supply chain models, motivated by Marketing and Psychological studies (e.g. [12, 13] that found it to be prevalent in (consumer) behavior.Let
be the prices and quantities in period 1, and similarly for period 2.2nd period:The demand model for the second period(*) is
where
is the effect of own price change, and
, the effect of competitor's price change. We shall assume that
.Note that if
and
the contribution of the first reference-price difference is negative, and of the second positive. If
and
, the signs of these contributions reverse, but the expressions remain the same.Also,
[noise has no effect]. Thus
Proposition 2In the symmetric case
. Note that the denominator is positive since
and
.
As for comparative statics,
is linear in
. It is increasing in v and c.
Or, in different form, if
increases in
and decreases in
.Now, moving to the first period,
and
As the denominator is independent of
, and positive, we shall focus on the numerator.It can be shown that
Thus
where
means “has the same sign as”.So 


sufficient conditions for
are
. These conditions hold with some restrictions on the parameters.
6. Concluding Remarks
We generalized the basic Bertrand model of differentiated duopoly in three ways: 1. Extension from two firms to three (tri-opoly). 2. Extension from linear to non-linear (convex) production costs (with two and three firms). 3. Extension to a two-period model where demand in the second depends also on the price in the first (reference price). Note that the term "reference effects" is used in some literature when the price of a product influences one's attitude to the price of another (e.g., [14]) which is a totally different meaning than our temporal "reference effect".The tri-opolists are shown to charge, under certain conditions, higher price than the duopolists (who charges a higher price than a monopolist). For non-linear costs, we used a quadratic function. We provide complete comparative statics.Our reference price model assumes that demand in the second period depends on one's own price difference and competitor's price difference between periods one and two. We find the optimal price and profit in the second period (as a function of the price in the first), then add to it the profit in the first period (which is also a function of the price in that period) and then optimize the sum over that price.One possible extensions is to embed non-linear production costs in the reference price model.One other possible generalization of the Bertrand model and its extensions is to assume a non-linear demand model, like
(e.g. [15] and references therein).Another direction is the extension of the reference price model to more than two periods (for a continuous time model where demand always also depends on the price at time zero, see Fibich et al. [16]).
Note
(*) For the first period, we still have
as in the basic model.
References
[1] | Bertrand, J. (1883) "Theorie Mathematique de la Richesse Sociale" Journal des Savants, 67, 449-508. |
[2] | Vives, X. (2001) Oligopoly Pricing: Old Ideas and New Techniques, The MIT Press. |
[3] | Mas-Collel, A., M.D. Whinston and J.R. Green (1995) Microeconomic Theory, Oxford University Press. |
[4] | Chesnes, M. (2012) "The Impact of Outages on Price and Investment in US Oil Refining Industry" Bureau of Economics, Federal Trade Commission, U.S.A. |
[5] | Zhao, W. and Y. Wang (2002) "Coordination of Joint Pricing-Production Decisions in Supply Chains" IIE Transactions, 34, 701-715. |
[6] | Häckner, J. (2000) "A Note on Price and Quantity Competition in Differentiated Oligopolies" Journal of Economic Theory, 93, 233-239. |
[7] | Popescu, I. and Y. Wu (2007) "Dynamic Pricing Strategies with Reference Effects", Operations Research, 55, 413-429. |
[8] | Güler, M.G., T. Bilgic and R. Güllü (2014) "Joint Inventory and Pricing Decisions with Reference Effects" IIE Transactions, 46, 330-343. |
[9] | Godes, D., E. Ofek and M. Sarvary (2009) "Content vs Advertising: The Impact of Competition on Media Firm Strategy" Marketing Science, 28(1), 20-35. |
[10] | Hsu, J. and X. H. Wang (2005) "On Welfare under Cournot and Bertrand's Competition in Differentiated Oligopolies", Review of Industrial Organization, 27, 185-101. |
[11] | Holt, C.C., F. Modigliani, J.F. Muth and H.A. Simon (1960) Planning, Production, Inventories and Workforce, Prentice-Hall. |
[12] | Helson, M. (1964) Adaptation Level Theory, Harper and Row, New York. |
[13] | Briesch, R.A., L. Krishnamutrhi, T. Mazumdar and S.P. Raj (1997) "A Comparative Analysis of Reference Price Models", Journal of Consumer Research 24, 202-214. |
[14] | Zhou, J. (2011) “Preference Dependence and Market Competition” Working Paper, University College, London. |
[15] | Askar, S.S. (2014) "On Cournot-Bertrand Competition with Differentiated Products" Annals of Operations Research, 223, 81-93. |
[16] | Fibich, G.A. Gavious and O. Lowengart (2007) "Optimal Price Promotion in the Presence of Asymmetric Reference-Price Effects" Managerial and Decision Economics, 28, 569-577. |