[1] | Burger, J. D. and S. J. K. Walters (2003), “Market size, pay, and performance: A general model and application to major league baseball," Journal of Sports Economics, vol. 4, no. 2, pp. 108-125. |
[2] | Cornes, R. and R. Hartley (2005), “Asymmetric contests with general technologies," Economic Theory, vol. 26, no. 4, pp. 923-946. |
[3] | Dietl, H. M.,E. Franck and M. Lang (2008), “Overinvestment in team sports leagues: A contest theory model," Scottish Journal of Political Economy, vol. 55, no. 3, pp. 353-368. |
[4] | El-Hodiri, M. and J. Quirk (1971), “An economic model of professional sports league," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 79, no. 6, pp. 1302-1319. |
[5] | Fort, R. and J. Quirk (1995), “Cross-subsidization, incentives, and outcomes in professional team sports leagues," Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 33, no. 3, pp. 1265-1299. |
[6] | Fort, R. and J. Winfree (2009), “Sports really are different: The contest success function and the supply of talent," Review of Industrial Organization, vol. 34, no. 1, pp. 69-80. |
[7] | Groot, L. (2008), Economics, Uncertainty and European Football: Trends in Competitive Balance, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. |
[8] | Hadley, L., M. Poitras, J. Ruggiero and S. Knowles (2000), “Performance evaluation of national football league teams," Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 21, no. 2, pp. 63-70. |
[9] | Horowitz, I. (1994), “On the manager as principal clerk," Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 15, no. 5, pp. 413-419. |
[10] | Kahn, H. (1993), “Managerial quality, team success, and individual player performance in major league baseball," Industrial and Labor Relations Review, vol. 46, no. 3, pp.531-547. |
[11] | Késenne, S. (2007), The Economic Theory of Professional Team Sports: An Analytical Treatment, Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar. |
[12] | Krautmann, A. C. (2009), “Market size and the demand for talent in major league baseball," Applied Economics, vol. 41, no. 25, pp. 3267-3273. |
[13] | Neal, W. C.(1964), “The peculiar economics of professional sports," Quarterly Journal of Economics, vol. 78, no. 1, pp. 1-14. |
[14] | Porter, P. K. and G. W. Scully (1982), “Measuring managerial efficiency: The case of baseball," Southern Economic Journal, vol. 48, no. 3, pp. 642-650. |
[15] | Quirk, J. and R. Fort (1992), Pay Dirt: The Business of Professional Team SportsPrinceton N.J.:Princeton University Press. |
[16] | Rottenberg, S. (1956), “The baseball players’ labor market," Journal of Political Economy, vol. 64, no. 3, pp. 242-258. |
[17] | Ruggiero, J., L. Hadley, G. Ruggiero and S. Knowles (1997), “A note on the pythagorean theorem of baseball production," Managerial and Decision Economics, vol. 18, no. 4, pp. 335-342. |
[18] | Singell, L. (1993), “Managers, specific human capital and firm productivity in major league baseball," Atlantic Economic Journal, vol. 21, no. 3, pp. 47-59. |
[19] | Szidarovszky, F. and S. Yakowitz (1977), “A new proof of the existence and uniqueness of the Cournot equilibrium," International Economic Review, vol. 18, no. 3, pp.787-789. |
[20] | Szymanski, S. (2003), “The economic design of sporting contests," Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 41, no. 4, pp. 1137-1187. |
[21] | Szymanski, S. and S. Késenne (2004), “Competitive balance and gate revenue sharing in team sports," Journal of Industrial Economics, vol. 52, no. 1, pp. 165-177. |
[22] | Vrooman, J. (1995), “A general theory of professional sports leagues," Southern Economic Journal, vol. 61, no. 4, pp. 971-990. |
[23] | Wolfstetter, E. (1999), Topics in Microeconomics: Industrial Organization, Auctions, and Incentives, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. |