American Journal of Economics

p-ISSN: 2166-4951    e-ISSN: 2166-496X

2017;  7(5): 249-258

doi:10.5923/j.economics.20170705.06

 

Macroeconomic and Household Welfare Impact of Increase in Minimum Wage in Nigeria: A Computable General Equilibrium Model

Philip Terhemen Abachi, Paul Terhemba Iorember

Department of Economics, Benue State University, Makurdi, Nigeria

Correspondence to: Philip Terhemen Abachi, Department of Economics, Benue State University, Makurdi, Nigeria.

Email:

Copyright © 2017 Scientific & Academic Publishing. All Rights Reserved.

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution International License (CC BY).
http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/

Abstract

Given the down turn of economic activities in Nigeria and the agitation for minimum wage increase, this study investigated the impact that increases in minimum wage will have on households welfare in Nigeria using a Computable General Equilibrium Model. The study formulated two scenarios – increase in minimum wage of workers by 211% and 150%, being increase from N18,000 to N56,000 and from N18,000 to N45,000 respectively. The data used for the study is a reformatted Social Accounting Matrix for Nigeria. The simulation results of scenario one revealed that, a 211% increase in the minimum wage of workers will increase agricultural output, industrial output and exports while imports will be depressed marginally and then lead to increase in households welfare indicators of income, consumption and savings by 6.76%, 5.0% and 3.61% respectively. The result of scenario two revealed that, increasing minimum wage by 150% will lead to increase in agricultural output, industrial output and exports while imports will fall and then households’ welfare indicators of income, consumption and savings will increase by 5.75%, 4.83% and 2.96% respectively. Similarly, the study found that, the Hicksian Equivalent variation as a measure of welfare impact of the policy is positive and high in all the simulations. The study concluded that an increase in minimum wage of workers has positive and significant impact on household welfare in Nigeria. Therefore, it is recommended among others that the government should as a matter of urgency accede to the demand of the organized labour and increase the minimum wage of workers from N18,000 to N56,000 (211% increase) and ensure that it is fully implemented across board.

Keywords: Minimum Wage, Household Welfare and Computable General Equilibrium

Cite this paper: Philip Terhemen Abachi, Paul Terhemba Iorember, Macroeconomic and Household Welfare Impact of Increase in Minimum Wage in Nigeria: A Computable General Equilibrium Model, American Journal of Economics, Vol. 7 No. 5, 2017, pp. 249-258. doi: 10.5923/j.economics.20170705.06.

1. Introduction

The global debate on the choice of an appropriate income policy as a response to inflation and a tool for boosting household welfare, reducing poverty and ensuring macroeconomic stability has been changing profoundly between minimum wage legislation and price control mechanisms. However, the focus of this study is on minimum wage rather than price control due to the fact that, the Nigerian economy is largely market driven and prices of goods and services are determined by the market forces.
Proponents of minimum wage increases such as Fanti and Gori (2011) and Watanabe (2013) have argued that increases in minimum wages serve as engine of macroeconomic growth, assist low-skilled individuals during downturns in the business cycle, reduce income inequality and reduce poverty. Samuel (2015) noted that, the main idea of fixing minimum wages is to ensure that low-wage-low-skill workers earn “decent” wages from their jobs. Moreover, it can “pull” households that are below the poverty line to somewhere above the poverty line since it raises household income. In addition, it creates and sustains at least, a “subsistence standard of living” for poor and low-skilled workers.
However, a review of the literature provides little empirical support for these claims. Minimum wage increases redistribute gross domestic product away from lower-skilled industries and toward higher-skilled industries and are largely ineffective in assisting the poor during both peaks and troughs in the business cycle (Sabia, 2014). Card and Krueger (1995) opined that, minimum wage increases may not be the most efficient way to achieve poverty reduction and improve household welfare. This is because, while increases in minimum wages reduce poverty levels, they also lead to higher levels of unemployment. Specifically, the category of workers most likely to suffer from minimum wage increases is low-skilled workers. Such workers are easily substituted for high-skilled workers. Unemployment increases most amongst them. This is worsened by the fact that jobs that require low skills and those that pay low wages are the most likely to decline when minimum wages increase (Neumark, 2014). Therefore, as far as efficiency is concerned, the ability of minimum wages to reduce poverty and improve household welfare is not costless (Lustig and McLeod, 1996). Similarly, Folawewo (2007) noted that wage increase brought about by minimum wage increases is usually counter-productive. Apart from leading to a rise in general price level, wage increases, are always followed by threat of reduction in government workforce, and in some cases, such threats have resulted into massive laid-off in the civil service (Olaleye, 1974; Owoye, 1994). Also, wage increases in Nigeria do not match up with the rate of increase in prices. As a result, there are always agitations from the labour unions for persistent wages and salaries increase as it is the case in Nigeria presently.
Aside the divergent findings about the poverty reduction and macroeconomic effects of minimum wage increases in an economy, the household welfare effect of the income policy (minimum wage increases) has received little attention in literature especially for Nigeria. More so, most of the studies reviewed in this paper have used partial analysis in analyzing specific economic effects of the income policy in an economy rather than general equilibrium analysis which according to Adams (1987) is most appropriate in analyzing macroeconomic effect of an economic policy. This study therefore analyses the impact that different levels of increases in minimum wage will have on macroeconomic variables of agricultural output, manufacturing output, export and import prices and on household welfare indicators of income, consumption and savings in Nigeria using Computable General Equilibrium model.
The study is significant because it is one of the few studies on the effect of minimum wage in Nigeria that adopts Computable General Equilibrium approach and is coming up at the time when agitations for increase in minimum wage is palpable in Nigeria. Hence, the study is not only timely but also contributory to the existing body of literature on both minimum wage and Computable General Equilibrium model. The findings of the study will provide insight and understanding to the government and policy makers on the impact of increase minimum wage on both macroeconomic variables and household welfare indicators. Therefore, the study can be said to be of immense benefit to the policy makers and economic planners in terms of using its findings in formulating and implementing appropriate policy measures towards accelerating economic growth and improving living conditions of the people.

2. Empirical Review

Several studies have investigated the impact of minimum wage on different aspects of the economy using varying methodologies. Mwangi, Simiyu and Onderi (2015) analysed the effects of minimum wage on the labour market and income distribution in Kenya using CGE. The study found a positive effect of minimum wage increase on household income and consumption, as well as government income. However the focus of the study was on income distribution rather than welfare. Also Erero (2016) used CGE model to investigate the effect of minimum wage in South Africa and found that an increase in the national minimum wage has a negative and distortive impact on the reported macro-economic variables. This is particularly seen by a decline in GDP, employment and welfare. These findings as it were are not based on Nigerian data and the failure to disaggregate welfare into income, consumption and savings does not explicitly capture the household impact. Adams (1987) used macroeconometric model to simulate the effect of changes in minimum wage on economic variables and found mixed outcomes; while it affects unemployment positively, it has negative effect on real wage and real gross national product. The study did not evaluate the household welfare effect of the policy. In Nigeria, Falawewo (2007) used Computable General Equilibrium model to analysed the effect of minimum wage policy in Nigeria. The study found that increase in minimum wage had a positive effect on the economy but could not include household savings which is also a major component of household welfare. Atseye, Takon and Ogar (2014) and Nwoke (2017) used partial equilibrium models to examine the impact of minimum wage on the Nigerian economy. The studies found positive effects on the economy but could not utilized the CGE model to address the economy-wide effect of the policy options. Akpansung (2014) investigated the effect of minimum wage increase on unemployment during democratic era using least squares and granger causality techniques. The study found that increases in minimum wage leads to increase in unemployment levels. No attention was given to welfare effect of the policy.

3. Theoretical Framework

Utility Theory and General Equilibrium Theory
This study is anchored on two theories: the Utility Theory and the General Equilibrium theory. The utility theory as espoused by Gossen (1854), Walras (1874), Marshall (1890) and Hicks and Allen (1939) posit that a consumer is assumed to be rational. Given his income and market prices of various commodities, he plans the spending of his income so as to attain highest possible satisfaction or utility. On the other hand, the general equilibrium theory developed by Arrow, Debreu and McKenzie in the 1950s seeks to explain a situation where all prices are in equilibrium; each consumer spends his given income in a manner that yields him the maximum satisfaction. Thus, the economy is in general equilibrium when commodity prices make each demand equal to its supply and factor prices make the demand for each factor equal to its supply so that all product markets and factor markets are simultaneously in equilibrium. This equilibrium position is sensitive to government intervention through the instrumentality of the minimum wage variation.
The theoretical underpinning of welfare impact of an economic policy such as increase in minimum wage is found in the utility theory. The theory posits that a consumer is assumed to be rational and therefore spends his income in a way that gives him highest welfare. The general equilibrium theory on the other hand seeks to explain a situation where both commodity prices and factor prices are simultaneously in equilibrium in the various markets. While the utility theory is useful in the estimation of the welfare impact of the policy change, the general equilibrium theory on the other hand addressed the economy-wide perspective of the study and as well formed the bedrock for the methodology of the study.

4. Methodology

The appropriate methodology to capture the macroeconomic and welfare impact of an income policy such as increase in minimum wage is the Computable General Equilibrium model (CGE). The CGE model belongs to a category of multisectoral models. It is useful in carrying out economy-wide impact of specific policies (Adenikinju, Falokun, Aminu and Fowowe, 2012). The choice of CGE model for this study is based on a number of reasons; first, given that an increase in minimum wage will have economy-wide effects on the Nigeria economy, CGE provides a framework for capturing such effects. Second, CGE models are also adept in addressing issues of optimization and in this case, utility optimization. CGE provides tools that can be relied upon to carry out such optimization exercise (Adenikinju et al, 2012). Also, the appropriateness of CGE model for this study is defined by the temporal structure (essentially static analysis) and the nature of data employed.
Model Specification and Discussion
The CGE model used in this study follows closely that of Lofgren, Harris and Robinson (2002) model which was also used by Anuwat (2010). The functions used are constant elasticity of substitution (CES) of both the Cobb- Douglas and the Leontief types. The structure of the model is divided into four major blocks: production and trade; price; institutions and system constraint blocks. The choice of these blocks is based on the macroeconomic nature of the study.
Production and Trade block
In this block, it is assumed that each producer maximizes profits subject to its production function, which uses the Cobb-Douglas production technology. There are two primary inputs: capital and labour which are influenced by increases in wages. Therefore, the activity production function can be expressed as;
(1)
Where is the activity level, quantity demanded of factor from activity is the production function share parameter or value-added share for factor in activity a and is the production efficient parameter.
Price Block
In the price block, domestic import price of commodity c in equation 2 is the product of world import price the tariff adjustment and exchange rate (EXR) plus transaction costs to move the commodity from the border to the domestic demander.
(2)
Where is import price in LCU (local-currency units) including transaction costs, is cost, insurance and freight (c.i.f.) import price in FCU (foreign-currency units), is import tariff rate, is exchange rate (LCU per FCU), is composite commodity price (including sales tax and transaction costs), is quantity of commodity c’ as trade input per imported unit of c.
The export price in LCU in equation 3 is the price received by domestic producers when they sell their output in export markets. Since export price is exogenously determined, increase in minimum wage will likely increase effective domestic demand and reduce the incentive to export.
(3)
Where is export price in LCU (local-currency units), is free on board (f.o.b.) export price in FCU (foreign-currency units), is export tax rate.
The absorption for each commodity is the total domestic spending on commodities at domestic prices (PQc QQc). It can be expressed as the spending on domestic outputs (PDc QDc) plus imports (PMcQMc) including an upward adjustment for sales tax as shown in equation 12. Therefore, the composite price (PQc) can be derived by dividing equation 4 by the composite supply (QQc). Increase in minimum wage will influence household spending behavior.
(4)
Where is quantity of goods supplied to domestic market (composite supply), is quantity sold domestically of domestic output, is quantity of imports of commodity, and is rate of sales tax (as share of composite price inclusive of tax).
Domestic output value at the producer price (PXcQXc) is the value of domestic sales (PDcQDc) plus the export value (PEcQEc). This can be expressed as equation 5. The producer price (PXc ) is derived by dividing equation 5 by the domestic output (QXc). Increases in minimum wage will likely affect domestic output given that, the volume of domestic sales will rise due to the changes in the purchasing power of the households.
(5)
Where is aggregate producer price for commodity, is aggregate marketed quantity of domestic output of commodity and is quantity of exports.
Equation 6 describes activity price (PAa), which is the sum of producer price times the yields of commodities. Similarly, activity price defined as gross revenue per activity unit is affected by increase in output yield due to increase in minimum wage.
(6)
Where is activity price (gross revenue per activity unit), is producer price of commodity c for activity , and is yield of output c per unit of activity.
Equation 7 describes, the value-added price, defined as the activity price minus the value added tax and input cost per activity unit.
(7)
Where is value-added price, is value added tax rate (indirect tax) is composite price and is input per activity unit.
Institution Block
Equation 8 defines the income of factor f (YFf ) (capital and labour) as equal to the sum of the average factor prices (WFf ) multiplied by the quantity demanded of factor f (QFfa) with distortion wage (WFDISTfa). This factor income is split among domestic institutions after payment of direct factor tax and transfers to the rest of the world. Labour income belongs to households inform of wages whereas capital income is subtracted from the payment of tax on capital before flowing to household and enterprise. Changes in minimum wage will affect total factor income.
(8)
Where YFf is total factor income of factor f, WFf is activity specific wage, is held constant with the assumption that, the increase in minimum wage will not result to wage distortion and QFfa is employment level.
Household income is the sum of factor incomes, transfers and remittances from abroad. Households’ disposable income is either saved or consumed. Equation 9 defines household consumption expenditure as household income net of indirect taxes and savings. Increasing minimum wage will likely affect household consumption ceteris paribus.
(9)
Where, EHh is household consumption expenditures, is share of net income, is a set of households, TINSh is direct tax rate for households, MPSh represents marginal propensity to save for household h and YIi is the income of institution i (in the set INSDNG).
Equation 10 defines quantity demand for investment for each commodity. It multiplies base-year investment demand (qinvc) by investment adjustment factor (IADJ).
(10)
Where, QINVc denotes quantity of fixed investment demand for commodity, IADJ denotes investment adjustment factor, and qinvc denotes the base-year quantity of fixed investment demand.
In terms of the government sector, its income and expenditure are shown in equations 11 and 12 respectively.
(11)
(12)
See Appendix A for definition of variables and parameters
System Constraint Block
The generations of factor incomes and payment of these incomes to domestic institutions links production with demand. Balance between demand and supply for both commodities and factors are needed in order for the model to reach equilibrium. This balance is imposed on the model through a series of system constraints (Thurlow, 2004).
The standard CGE model defined three macro-balances: commodity markets, factor markets and external balances. Equations in this block define the system constraints that must be satisfied by the model. Commodity and factor markets are cleared by the flexible prices while current account balance is cleared by foreign exchange rate. The model satisfies Walras’ law. Therefore, the macro constraint satisfies the identity in equation 16, which means savings equal investment.
The equilibrium in the factor market is defined in equation 13, which is the equality in total quantity demanded and supplied of the two factors (capital and labour).
(13)
Where is quantity demanded of factor f from activity a and is total quantity supplied of factor f.
Similarly, equilibrium in the commodity market expressed in equation 14 is the equality in composite commodity supply and demand.
(14)
Where QINTca is quantity of commodity c as intermediate input to activity a, QHch is quantity consumed for commodity c by household h, qpc is base-year quantity of government demand and QINVc is quantity of investment demand for commodity.
Regarding the current account balance (expressed in foreign currency), the country’s earnings equal its spending of foreign exchange, which is represented by equation 15.
(15)
Where is foreign savings (FCU) (exogenous variable).
Another macro constraint is the saving-investment balance as shown in equation 16. Total savings are the sum of savings from households, enterprises, government and the rest of the world. In contrast, total investment is the sum of the value of domestic investment and foreign investment. The WALRAS variable is introduced in this equation in order to check whether the saving-investment balance holds. If the model works, the value of WALRAS will be zero (Anuwat, 2010).
(16)
See Appendix A for definition of variables and parameters.
Simulation Designs
To achieve the objective of this study, a Computable General Equilibrium model was employed, calibrated on data from Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for Nigeria to simulate the impact of increases in minimum wage on household welfare and macroeconomic variables. The scenarios used in this study represented exogenous change in economic conditions and were compared to a baseline scenario which assumes no specific changes to policy. The two scenarios compared with the baseline scenario are: (i) 211% increase in minimum wage of workers (increase from 18,000 to 56,000) in line with the demand of the organized labour and (ii) 150% increase in minimum wage of workers (i.e increase from 18,000 to 45,000). A position that is favoured by the government and appears similar to the 2011 template that increased minimum wage by 150% (from 7,000 to the present 18,000).

5. Evaluation of Macroeconomic and Welfare Impact of the Minimum Wage Policy

The macroeconomic variables or indicators of interest in this study are agricultural output; industrial output; exports and imports. The choice of these variables is based on the sensitivity of the variables to the structure of the Nigerian economy. The variables were selected to account for both the aggregate domestic demand and current account dynamics.
On the side of welfare, Obi-Egbedi, Okoruwa, Aminu and Yusuf (2012) identified three basic components/indicators of household welfare namely; households consumption, income and savings. To evaluate the implications of the minimum wage policy options on household welfare in Nigeria, the Hicksian Equivalent Variation was estimated by calculating welfare gains/losses from simulation results. Following Olopoenia and Aminu (2007), Annabi, Khondker, Raihan, Cockburn and Decaluwe (2006) and Devarajan, Thienfelder and Suthiiwart (2001). The Hicksian Equivalent Variation (EV) is given by
(17)
Where is the income of household h before the policy change, is the utility of household h before the policy change, is the utility of household h after the policy change and is the Equivalent Variation of a household h. A policy is said to have impact on households if the calculated value of the equivalent variation is greater than zero (i.e, if EV > 0). The greater the value of the equivalent variation, the more impactful the policy is to the households.

6. Data Sources

The main source of data for this paper is the updated Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) constructed from (i) 2006 SAM which is the most recent for Nigeria (ii) Sectoral output data for year 2015 reported by the Central Bank of Nigeria (2015) (iii) Year 2015 households’ income and expenditure data for Nigeria reported by the National Bureau of Statistics (NBS) (2015) and the CBN (2015). The 2006 Nigeria SAM was built for the dynamic CGE (DCGE) that examined the agricultural growth and investment options for poverty reduction in Nigeria. It comprises 61 sectors/activities out of which 34 are under agriculture and 12 under manufacturing; 12 household groups and 3 factors of production. It also includes an account for government and the rest of the world (Nwafor, Diao and Alpuerto, 2010). However, to achieve the objectives of the study, these sectors (Agriculture and Industrial) and the household groups are aggregated to construct the SAM Table.

7. Estimation and Analysis of Result

The simulation results of the two scenarios is presented in Tables 1 and 2 respectively.
Table 1. Impact of Increase in Minimum Wage by 211% increase (i.e. increase from N18,000 to N56,000) on Macroeconomic variables and Households’ Welfare in Nigeria
     
Table 2. Impact of Increase in Minimum Wage by 150% (i.e. increase from N18,000 to N45,000) on Macroeconomic variables and Households’ Welfare in Nigeria
     
Result in Table 1 shows that, the macroeconomic variables of agricultural output, industrial output and export will increase by 4.13%, 3.65% and 7.12% respectively while imports will reduce marginally by 1.05%. This change will lead to a single digit increase in all the household welfare indices of income, consumption and savings. Households income, consumption and savings will increase by 6.76%; 5.0% and 3.61% respectively. Also, the result of the simulation shows that households consumption of domestic goods will increase by 5.41% while households consumption of imported goods on the other hand will depress -0.41% change. This indicates that increase in minimum wage will drive consumption of domestic goods.
The Hicksian Equivalent Variation is 974.14 which shows that, welfare of households will be better off if the minimum wage of workers is increased from N18,000 minimum to N56,000 (i.e 211% increase).
Result in Table 2 shows that, the macroeconomic variables of agricultural output, industrial output and export will increase by 3.52%, 3.70% and 5.31% respectively while imports will marginally depress by 1.18%. This change will lead to a single digit increase in all the household welfare indices of income, consumption and savings. Households income, consumption and savings will increase by 5.75%; 4.83% and 2.96% respectively. Also, the result of the simulation shows that households consumption of domestic goods will increase by 5.11% while households consumption of imported goods on the other hand will depress 0.28% change. This indicates that increase in minimum wage will encourage consumption of domestic goods.
The Hicksian Equivalent Variation of 933.87 shows that, welfare of households will be better off if the minimum wage of workers is increased from N18,000 minimum to N45,000 (i.e 150% increase). Graphically, the percentage change in simulations 1 and 2 is presented in Figure 1.
Figure 1. Graphic Presentation of percentage change in simulations 1 and 2
The positive effect of increase in minimum wage on macroeconomic variables for both scenarios is consistent with the findings of Folawewo (2007 who found that increase in minimum wage has positive effect on productivity in all sectors of the economy. Similarly, the positive impact of increases in minimum wage on household welfare as shown by the positive and high values of the Hicksian Equivalent Variation for both scenarios may be so due to the fact that, increases in income is associated with increase in consumption even though disproportionately as expressed by the Keynes Absolute income hypothesis. This finding is consistent with the finding of Folawewo (2007) who found that a rise in minimum has positive effects on household income and consumption.

8. Conclusions and Policy Recommendations

All the two policy options (211% and 150% increase in minimum wage) simulated indicated that, increase in minimum wage have positive impact on macroeconomic variables of agricultural output, industrial output, export and imports in Nigeria. This finding is consistent with the findings of Falawewo (2007) who found that increase in minimum wage had a positive effect on the economy. The finding on the other hand is inconsistent with the finding of Erero (2016) who found that an increase in the national minimum wage has a negative and distortive impact on the reported macro-economic variables.
The study also found that increase in minimum wage has positive impact on household welfare indicators of income and consumption and savings in Nigeria. The positive values of the equivalent variation for all the two policy scenarios indicated that, the policy of increasing minimum wage has positive impact on household welfare in Nigeria with the 211% increase having greater impact. This finding is consistent with the finding of Mwangi, Simiyu and Onderi (2015) who found a positive effect of minimum wage increase on household income and consumption.
Based on this, government should as a matter of urgency comply with the demand of the organized labour and increase minimum wage of workers from N18,000 to N56,000 (211% increases) or from N18,000 to N45,000 (150% increase) and ensure that it is fully implemented at all levels of governance. This increase in minimum wage apart from directly increasing households income and consumption levels, will raise aggregate demand and spur economic activities within the economy which will in turn ensure positive economic growth.

Appendix A: Mathematical Summary Statement for Standard CGE Model

Sets
Parameters (Latin Letters)
Exogenous Variables
Endogenous Variables

References

[1]  Adams, G. (1987), Increasing the Minimum Wage: The Macroeconomic Impacts, Briefing Paper, Economic Policy Institute, Washington, DC.
[2]  Adenikinju, A., Falokun G., Aminu A. and Fowowe B. (2012). Macroeconomic Impact Analysis in The Impact of the Nigeria LNG Project on Nigeria, edited by Adenikinju A., Fowowe B. and Ola-Peters J. (2012). CEAR Monograph Series 2.
[3]  Annabi, N., Khondker, B., Raihan, S., Cockburn J. & Decaluwe, B. (2006). Implications of WTO agreements and unilateral trade policy reforms for poverty in Bangladesh: Short versus long-run impacts. World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 3976.
[4]  Anuwat P. (2010). The Impact of capital intensive farming in Thailand: A Computable General Equilibrium Approach. Unpublished Ph.D Thesis. Lincoln University.
[5]  Atseye, F.A., Takon S.M. and Ogar O.A. (2014). Impact of National Minimum Wage on Low Income Workers in Calabar Municipality, Nigeria. Developing Country Studies 4(26).
[6]  Breisinger C., Thomas M., & Thurlow J. (2009). Social Accounting matrices and multiplier analysis. International Food Policy Research Institute.
[7]  Card, D. and Krueger, A.B. (1994), Minimum Wages and Empoyment: A Case Study of the Fast-Food Industry in New Jersey and Pennsylvania’, American Economic Review, 84 (4):772-793.
[8]  Devarajan, S., Thienfelder, K.E, & Suthiiwart, S. (2001). The marginal cost of public funds in developing countries, in Amedeo Fossati Wolfyang Wiegard. Policy evaluation with computable general equilibrium models, Routledge, New York.
[9]  Erero J.L. (2016). National minimum wage in South Africa: A Computable General Equilibrium Model Analysis. Economic Research Southern Africa (ERSA) Working Paper 650.
[10]  Fanti L., and Gori L. (2011) “On Economic Growth and Minimum Wages”. Munich Personal RePec Archive, MPRA Paper No. 25842.
[11]  Folawewo, A. O. (2007), “Macroeconomic effects of minimum wage in Nigeria: A general equilibrium analysis”. Paper Prepared for presentation at the CSEA Conference 2007: Economic Development in Africa, Oxford, 19-20 March.
[12]  Gossen, H.H. (1854). The Laws of human relations and the rules of human action derived Therefrom. Cambridge: MIT Press.
[13]  Hicks, John (1939). The foundations of welfare economics. The Economic Journal, 49 (196): 696–712.
[14]  Hicks. J. R. (1941). “The rehabilitation of consumers’ surplus.” Review of Economic Studies 108-16.
[15]  Kesheb R.B. (2001). Welfare and distributional impacts of financial liberalization in Nepal. Centre for Economic Policy Business School, University of Hull.
[16]  Ketebo J.H. (2012). The impacts of public spending on economic growth and poverty reduction in Ethiopia: A dynamic computable general equilibrium analysis. Unpublished PhD Thesis, Addis Ababa University.
[17]  Lofgren, H., Harris, R. L. & Robinson, S. (2002). A standard computable general equilibrium (CGE) model in GAMS. Microcomputers in Policy Research. International Food Policy Research Institute.
[18]  Lustig N. and McLeod D. (1996) “Minimum Wages and Poverty in Developing Countries: Some Empirical Evidence”. Brookings Discussion Papers in International Economics, No.125.
[19]  Marshall A. (1890). Principles of economics, London and New York, McMillan.
[20]  Mwangi, T., Simiyu, F. and Onderi A. (2015). The effects of minimum wages on the labour market and income distribution in Kenya – a CGE analysis.
[21]  National Bureau of Statistics (2016). Statistical Bulletin.
[22]  Neumark D. (2014) “Employment Effects of Minimum Wages”. IZA World of Labor 2014:6. Ofori-Abebrese, G. (2012) “A Co-Integration Analysis of Growth in Government Expenditure in Ghana”. Journal of African Development, 14(1). 47-61.
[23]  Nwoke S.N. (2017). Effects of Minimu Wage in Public Sector on Selected Macroeconomic Variables in Nigeria. University of Nigeria Nsukka. Institutional Repository.
[24]  Nwafor, M., Diao X. and Alpuerto V. (2010). “A 2006 SAM for Nigeria. Methodology and Result”. Nigeria Strategy Support Program (NSSP) Report No.7 International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington, D.C.
[25]  Obi-Egbedi, O., Okoruwa, V., Aminu, A. and Yusuf, S. (2012). Effect of rice trade policy on household welfare in Nigeria. European Journal of Business and Management, 4(8), 160-170.
[26]  Olaleye, O (1974), ‘Labour and Politics in Nigeria: 1945-71’, Heinemann Publishers, Ibadan.
[27]  Olopoenia, A.A. & Aminu, A. (2007). Implementing welfare improving tax policy reforms: A computable general equilibrium analysis for Nigeria. 12th annual conference of the African Econometric Society. Cape Town, South Africa.
[28]  Owoye, O. (1994), “Wage Determination and Strike Activity in Nigeria”, Journal of African Economics, 3 (3): 447-80.
[29]  Promise A. and Kanayo A. (2011). Minimum Wage in Nigeria: Challenges and Human Resources Practitioners Intervention. Labour Law Review. NJLIR 5(3), 51-57.
[30]  Sabia, J.J. (2015). Do Minimum Wage Stimulate Productivity and Growth? IZA World of Labor, doi: 10.15185/izawol.221.
[31]  Samuelson, P. A. & William D.N. (2004). Economics. Mc Graw-Hill.
[32]  Samuel K.O. (2015). An empirical analysis of the relationship between minimum wage, investment and economic growth in Ghana. African Journal of Economic Review, 3(2), 84-101.
[33]  Thurlow, J. (2004). A dynamic computable general equilibrium (CGE) model for South Africa, Trade and Industrial Policy Strategies (TIPS), pp.1-99.
[34]  Walras, L. (1874). Elements of pure economics. Translated by Willian Jaffe (1954). Homewood, IU. Richard D. Irwin.
[35]  Wolf, E., and Nadiri, M. (1981): "A Simulation Model of the Effect of an Increase in the Minimum Wage on Employment, Output and the Price Level," Report of the Minimum Wage Paper Commission, 6, 217-232.