Applied Mathematics

p-ISSN: 2163-1409    e-ISSN: 2163-1425

2013;  3(4): 132-143

doi:10.5923/j.am.20130304.04

HIV/AIDS Prevalence and Transmission Risks from Mother to Child during the Pregnancy Process in Sub-saharan Africa

Diana Loubaki

Department of Economics, Institut CEDESC, Clamart, 92140, France

Correspondence to: Diana Loubaki, Department of Economics, Institut CEDESC, Clamart, 92140, France.

Email:

Copyright © 2012 Scientific & Academic Publishing. All Rights Reserved.

Abstract

This paper investigates the life dynamics properties of pregnant HIV/AIDS infected women with a joint utility function expressing both the mother and her future baby health states during the pregnancy process in Sub-Saharan Africa where medical-care shortages and delays to learn about the infection exist. Non separability of the utility function makes life dynamics oscillate caused by HIV/AIDS prevalence which generates transmission risks of the pandemic to the baby and presents cycles as well as hopf bifurcation while life fluctuates endogenously over time. Applying those results to the Cobb Douglas utility and production functions we find that optimal life dynamics existence and stability depend on illness gravity and medical care investment interaction.

Keywords: HIV/AIDS, Transmission Risk, Infection Gravity,Medical Care, Oscillatory Dynamics, Optimal Path

Cite this paper: Diana Loubaki, HIV/AIDS Prevalence and Transmission Risks from Mother to Child during the Pregnancy Process in Sub-saharan Africa, Applied Mathematics, Vol. 3 No. 4, 2013, pp. 132-143. doi: 10.5923/j.am.20130304.04.

1. Introduction

This article develops a theoretical model focused on HIV/AIDS acquisition and prevalence in order to establish optimal life dynamics stability when HIV/AIDS transmission risks from mother to child during the pregnancy process exists in Sub-Saharan Africa because of difficulties to fight the pandemic in the area. The analysis deals both with infected and non infected pregnant women where the first deals with optimal growth methods of investigation and the second with oscillatory dynamics methods in order to establish optimal dynamic paths existence and stability since a healthy pregnant woman at her pregnancy beginning time may came out to be infected along her birth gift process. The application of the theory to the Cobb Douglas function highlights a suitable prevention method which shows that optimal life dynamics existence and stability depend on illness gravity and medical care investment interaction.
The scientific contribution of this article holds on a unified study of optimal and oscillatory dynamical systems tools in the same growth model applied to the establishment of a steady state in lives dynamics target. Whereas most of the study based on HIV/AIDS in growth models focus on its impact on GDP, human capital accumulation of orphans and labor productivity, this article looks for lives preservation for population growth stability. Finally, the existence of transmission risk possibility of the pandemic along the birth process may create optimal or oscillatory dynamics in Sub-Saharan Africa, thus cycles and hopf bifurcation may appear because the utility function is no more additively separable and no more ensures optimal path existence and stability.
The human immunodeficiency virus (HIV) pandemic is one of the most serious health crises the world is facing today. AIDS has killed more than 25 million people since 1981 and an estimated 38.6 million people are now living with HIV, about 2.3 million of them are children[1]. Since 1999, primarily as a result of HIV, average life expectancy has declined in 38 countries. In the most severely affected countries, average life expectancy is now 49 years i.e 13 years less than in the absence of AIDS[2]. A disproportionate burden has been placed on women and children, who in many settings continue to experience high rates of new HIV infections and of HIV-related illness and death. In 2005 alone, an estimated 540 000 children were newly infected with HIV, with about 90% of these infections occurring in Sub-Saharan Africa. Most children living with HIV acquire the infection through mother-to-child transmission (MTCT), which can occur during pregnancy, labor and delivery or during breastfeeding. In the absence of any intervention the risk of such transmission is 15–30% in non-breastfeeding populations. Breastfeeding by an infected mother increases the risk by 5–20% to a total of 20–45%[3]. The risk of MTCT can be reduced to under 2% by interventions that include antiretroviral (ARV) prophylaxis given to women during pregnancy and labor and to the infant in the first weeks of life, obstetrical interventions including elective caesarean delivery (prior to the onset of labor and rupture of membranes), and complete avoidance ofbreastfeeding [4]-[6]. With these interventions, new HIV infections in children are becoming increasingly rare in many parts of the world, particularly in high-income countries where research has focused on more complex regimens and has shown that triple-ARV combinations given to women during pregnancy and labor can reduce the risk of transmission to under 2% [7]-[9]. These regimens are discontinued after childbirth for women without indications for ART (antiretroviral therapy). Since around 1998[10], triple-ARV combinations have increasingly been used to prevent MTCT; currently the majority of pregnant women living with HIV in Europe and North America receive such regimens[11]. In these settings and without breastfeeding, HIV infection in infants has been nearly eliminated. In contrast, Sub-Saharan Africa accounted for 69% of all new infections and nearly half of all HIV-related deaths globally. While 8 million people worldwide can access treatment, nearly 7 million additional people in need of access did not have it as of 2011. Moreover, for every one person on treatment, two are infected. Without effective HIV prevention, the number of people requiring treatment will become unsustainable. Despite the increase in AIDS funding during the past decade, financing gaps persist (International assistance declined from $7.6 billion in 2009 to $6.9 billion in 2010.), and the bulk of likely available funds is unpredictable and mainly for treatment. As new infections rise, country and donor investments in prevention are not being sustained. Efforts are actually targeted for prevention of mother-to-child transmission of HIV, in helping countries accelerate progress on maternal and child health, in line with the 2015 Millennium Development Goals (World Bank Weekly update, November 28, 2012). ARV Drugs treats Pregnant Women and Prevent HIV Infection in Infants are consistent and the Call to Action towards an HIV free and AIDS-free Generation explain the need to study the impact of HIV/AIDS for the case of MTCT in order to develop prevention tools in Sub-Saharan Africa. Therefore, this analysis models the situations of ARV Drugs for Treating Pregnant Women and Preventing HIV infection in Infants to support, the Call to Action Towards an HIV free and AIDS-free Generation. Indeed, the classification made applies pregnant women infected by HIV/AIDS virus investigation methods of oscillating optimal paths where the solution may not exist in growth literature. In the concern of pregnant women where infection is free, optimal stable path can be found because of HIV/AIDS absence. When the mother is infected by HIV/AIDS and may transmit it to the future baby, optimal dynamics oscillates and presents both cycles and Hopf bifurcation at critical points. In that case, the social planner uses the utility function which is no more additively separable but jointly expressed explaining more cares on lives preservation since they are no more submitted to natural birth process (see figures 1 and 2).
Figure 1. Comprehensive for the prevention of MTCT: women seen during pregnancy
Figure 2. Comprehensive for the prevention of MTCT: women seen during labour
Since Ramsey[12], dynamic growth models have been built in order to provide precise conditions which ensure convergence of optimal paths to the long-run equilibrium. Thus, the aggregate growth model analyzed by Cass and Koopmans[13]-[14] form the basis for much of the intuition economists have about long-run growth through precise criteria established using suitable assumptions. In standard one sector dynamic models since the representative agent's utility function is concave, the optimal path is monotone and converges to the steady state for all given production function. But when the central planner takes account of the life cycle of each agent in the economy, preferences have to be additively separable[15]-[16]. Because the main problem due to dynamic optimizing model is related to the existence of a social optimum which may lead to the non finiteness of objective functions when maximizing a discounted sum of integral over an infinite horizon raising the possibility that feasible exogenous variable paths grow so fast that the objective function is not finite and the optimum fail to exist. Conditions that ensure convergence of optimal path to the long run equilibrium generally depend on discount factor and concavity properties of utility and production function [17]-[18] Without the acceptance of the quoted properties conditions, dynamic growth models may oscillate and in some circumstances present cycles[19]-[20]. Indeterminacy theorems provided by Boldrin and Montrucchio[21] and Sorger[22] show that virtually every dynamics is compatible with the usual assumptions of concavity, perfect competition and perfect foresight. When the utility function of the representative agent is not additively separable, optimal paths don't necessarily converge to the steady state and appears that the optimal solution oscillates and presents cycles since the cross derivative of the indirect utility function is negative[23].
In parallel, the macroeconomics effects of HIV/AIDS on growth can be summarized in three approaches, the ‘first approach doesn’t incorporate the effects of ARV (anti retroviral drugs) provision on life expectancy studies. Those macroeconomic models show little decrease of HIV/AIDS impact on growth[24]-[27] or even an increase in per capita GDP growth because HIV-related declines in GDP are offset by increased mortality and population decline[28]. The second approach incorporates the effects of ARV provision on life expectancy and emphasizes different mechanics, that of reduced fertility in response to the epidemic[29]-[38]. However, the main problem with efforts to model the macroeconomic effects of HIV/AIDS in Africa is that projections hinge crucially on assumptions made about micro-level behavioral responses of individuals which leads to the tendency of micro studies of HIV/AIDS mostly provided[39]-[40]. The third approach of HIV/AIDS studies the way it can be assimilated to a perfect foresight dynamics[41]-[47]. Goldstein and al[48] show that pregnant women whose first clinic visit coincides with the nurse’s attendance are 58 percentage points more likely to test for HIV and 46 percent more likely to deliver in a hospital. Furthermore, women with high pretest expectations of being HIV positive, whose visit coincides with nurse attendance, are 25 and 7.4 percentage points more likely to deliver in a hospital and receive PMTCT (prevention of mother to child transmission) medication and 9 percentage points less likely to breast-feed than women whose visit coincides with nurse absence. The shortcomings that prevent pregnant women from testing on a subsequent visit are common in sub-Saharan Africa. In contrast, our article presents a theoretical framework dealing with HIV/AIDS transmission risks from mother to child during the pregnancy process in order to look for required conditions for optimal steady state in life terms. The article presents theoretical tools first and applies them to the concrete case of infection risks for the baby. Medical care and economic growth expressed by the discount factor conjugate to establish optimal paths. We find that optimal dynamics depend on illness gravity and medical care investment interaction.
The article is based on Michel and Venditti[49] on the one hand and on Groenka and Liu[50] on the other hand. It is organized like follow, section 2 presents the theory, section 3 applies the theory to specific functions and section 4 concludes.

2. The Theoretical Model

This article presents the required tools to study optimal growth and oscillatory dynamics. The first case refers to the healthy future mothers for whom life gift doesn’t fluctuate in contrast to the second case where life has uncertainty character in his gift activity because of HIV/AIDS disease and medical care shortages. We want to understand the way the baby’s life fluctuates endogenously according to his mother’s health state in an economic environment where prevail health care shortages and delays to learn about the infection prevalence in Sub-Saharan Africa.

2.1. The Additively Separable Case: the Non Infected Future Mothers

This first part presents the theory in the case of per-capita non infected pregnant woman by HIV/AIDS virus denoted stmh whose womb is carrying a baby, st+1ch. The main purpose of the analysis is to present useful tools which allow the study of how the mother's organism can be prevent from the HIV/AIDS virus infection and its transmission to the baby during the pregnancy process. The control is done in order to know if changes outcome i.e if the mother turns out to be infected at a given time during the pregnancy process, then tools control used change to slow the infection gravity in such a way that the pregnancy process reaches its end and ensure that the new born will be healthy and live the required time which is two periods. The pregnancy process takes place during the first period before the birth of the baby who born at the end of that first period and is young during the second period when his mother dies at the end of the second period.
The instantaneous utility function is additively separable in the non HIV/AIDS infection case. The healthy parameters are indexed by h whereas the mother and the child parameters are respectively indexed by m and c.
Assumption1: the instantaneous additively separable utility function is strictly increasing with respect to each argument i.e and , concave i.e and and C2 over the interior of the set Nth (total stock of non infected pregnant women) where ==∞
Optimal strategy for the couple of per-capita mother and her future baby combines the utilities of successive generations in order to guarantee life along the time periods such that:
(2.1)
Where δ Є[0,1] is the discount factor, s0mh is a given healthy pregnant woman at initial period t≥0.
The non infected pregnant women stock may vary along the pregnancy process in the way that, they may be infected by their partners before having given birth i.e before the end of the pregnancy process. There thus exists an infection risk parameter γtj≻0 where j=m,c which may make lives vary and alter health through possible increase of infection's gravity and attains the future baby's health and life expectancy because of delays to learn about the illness and the gravity generated.
The concavity property of the additively instantaneous utility function holds on the variables (stmh, st+1ch), per-capita optimal program becomes:
(2.2)
Note that, since γm>0 , then as we’ll see later on that the instantaneous utility function is no more additively separable but turns out to be joint and is thus out of this case study.
Healthcare is ensured by a stock of investment Kt+1h (which may be given by the donors in cooperation with the poor country government). The production of healthcare provided by the social planner is a neoclassical production function with respect to the following assumption:
Assumption 2: The function is C² and homogenous of degree 1 with respect to capital stock of drugs produced for the use of, the mother and the future baby's health states include in the interior of the set Nth2. Moreover, , and capital fully depreciates on use along the pregnancy care provision.
Assuming that capital fully depreciates on use, per-capita financial constraint in association to life process in the economy is expressed such that: and per-capita stationary capital is determinate by is the return and cost equilibrium relationship i.e . The expected lives care production function can be expressed in per-capita terms i.e is per-capita healthcare production provided by per-capita investment devoted to both the mother and the forthcoming child health states. Thus growth in life expectancy gain is such that
(2.3)
Proposition1: Let γm be the mother's HIV/AIDS infection risk parameter and γc be the HIV/AIDS transmission risk from the mother to the child parameter, if γm≻0 then the additively separable utility function uth(stmh,st+1ch) converges to the non separable utility function uti(stmi,st+1ci)
PROOF: if γm>0 for a given stmh then there exist γc≥0 associated to st+1ch such that stmh=ρ(γm) and st+1ch=ρ(γc)stmh therefore, (stmh, st+1ch)=stmh(1,ρ(γm)). Indeed, it can’t be find i)i=1,2 such that λ1stmh2stch=0 lead to i)i=1,2=0 for all i. Thus u(λ1stmh2stch)≤λ1u(stmh)+λ2u(st+1ch)=(λ12ρ(γc))u(stmh)≠ v(stmh)+ w(st+1ch). Indeed since γm>0 for a given stmh, then t≥0 we have: ∑[v(stmh)+w(st+1ch).]≠∑[u(stmh, stch)] which yields to uh(stmh, st+1ch) converges to ui(stmi, st+1ci) since γm >0 for a given stmh

2.2. The Non-separable Case

In this case, per-capita pregnant woman is infected by the virus HIV/AIDS at the beginning time or during her pregnancy process and thus the deal becomes first avoid her death occurrence before the end of the pregnancy time. Second, because her health alteration degree may be higher than expected, medical affords are conducted in a joint way both for the mother and her baby knowing that the mother's health alteration impact on the future baby may be greater than expected due to HIV/AIDS prevalence and transmission susceptibility since medical care requirement is under the needs. Indeed, this case is studied using a non separable utility function and optimal steady state may not exist since the mother's health alteration caused by the pandemic is too great to be saved on time i.e has crossed critical bound allowing the human organism survive until birth outcomes. Thus life dynamics oscillates i.e is uncertain and presents cycles when the virus transmission to the baby is avoid or eventually be chaotic when it is not possible anymore to converge to the steady state and death occurrence is non reversible. Therefore, the goal is to look for necessary existence conditions of a stable equilibrium in life dynamics prevention both for the mother and the baby. In contrast to the previous case, now infections risks for the baby are greater without prevention and treatment. Both the analytical problem and the tools used are more complex and deal with oscillatory dynamics in order to establish optimality conditions at each step.
The departure point is financial support equation which remains almost the same than before but now variables are indexed with i (infection) instead of h (healthy). The mother and the child beneficiate from medical treatment supported by a non significant investment i.e where because of more health state damages done by the pandemic inside the body's organism, indeed we have - where is per-capita future baby inside the womb and means that financial funds support the baby and the mother's health, f(kti) is healthcare provision. Therefore in the next period, the baby’s health evolution follows, which means that the baby’s stock grows since healthcare quality access is free. In our case, his life depends on his mother's health state in accordance to the virus transmission possibility during the pregnancy. The economic problem can be expressed such that
(2.4)
The instantaneous utility function uti(stmi, st+1ci)= uti(stmim ), st+1ci)(γc)) is no more additively separable like in the previous case where the study made before determinate a stable optimal path. If δ=1, the objective is not properly defined because the sum of the infinite may not converge and Ramsey cannot applied.
Now it is easier to formulate the problem through the use of the indirect utility function i.e
constrained to where sci is per-capita future baby carried by a pregnant woman which medical care tries to protect in order to make it becoming a baby at the end of the period, stci=st+1ci is child alive at the beginning of the second period. Using the change of variable such that xi =ai - smi it yields fxi)- sci =bi , the indirect utility function becomes:
(2.5)
We can also consider the reduced form of the optimal growth model in defining a smaller life production possibility set. Let consider the non empty set Ei to be a subset of total pregnant HIV/AIDS infected women Ni such that Ei={(ai, bi) / ai≥0 and 0≤bi≤f(xi)}. Since f is a continuous and a strictly concave function, Ei is a closed convex set. If (ai, bi) Ei , then ai is the input and bi is the feasible output per young. There exist a level x* such that if 0<xi ≤x* then x*≥f(xi)≥xi. Under those assumptions, let us consider the set: E1i={(ai, bi)ЄEi / }Ni2 , thus E1i is a compact convex set.
Proposition2: If the instantaneous utility function ui(smi, sci) and the production function f(ki) are continuous, increasing and concave, then the indirect utility function V(ai, bi) is concave over E1i
The proof if given in[47]
Consider the indirect utility function, under the assumptions 1 and 2, the maximum is necessarily interior and is characterized by the first order condition i.e U1(xi*, ai, bi)=0 in the other words we have:
To prove uniqueness of xi* we need to study the concavity with respect to xi* of the function ui(-xi+ai, bi+f(xi)) whose derivative with respect to xi is U1(xi, ai, bi)
The second derivative with respect to xi is therefore:
Where:
Because of the concavity of u and f then U11i>0 meaning that ui(-xi+ai, -bi+f(xi)) function is not strictly concave with respect to xi therefore, using the implicit function theorem through which we can express x* as a function of ai ,bi i.e xi*(ai ,bi) such that:
Which expresses analytically such that:
To fully determinate the concavity of the indirect utility function we may compute its second derivatives and use the Shepard lemma through which we obtain
and
therfore V is a function and satisfies:
;
Concavity of V implies V11≤0 and V22≤0 and is verified
Therefore we clarified using the implicit function theorem that a unique xi* exist and can be written such that xi*=xi*(ai*,bi*), now we need to establish its stability.

2.3. Study of Local Stability of the Steady State in a Non separable Case

As in the standard one sector optimal growth models, the stationary capital stock is given by the modified golden rule and doesn't depend on the agents' utility function. Therefore steady state can be expressed such that:
(2.5)
Because capital fully depreciates in one period and δ is the discount factor, stationary mother and baby born stocks are expressed by the following conditions:
(2.6)
(2.7)
Depending on the sign of the indirect utility function's cross derivative V₁₂ the sustainable dynamics may be monotone or oscillating.
Proposition3: let be an optimal sustainable path and let where is per-capita baby or new born
If , then the optimal dynamics is monotone
If , then the optimal dynamics is oscillating
The sign of V₁₂ must be evaluated around the steady state neighborhood (ai*, ai*). In our framework, we obtain:
Lemma1: if and only if where ≥0 is the determinant of the Hessian matrix of ui evaluated at (smi, sci)
PROOF
is the determinant of the Hessian matrix of ui evaluated at (smi, sci) and f′=δ⁻¹
The sign of the instantaneous utility function's cross derivative u₁₂i plays a fundamental role. Indeed, if u₁₂i≤0 (or u₁₂i≻0 but not too strong) then V₁₂≽0 (or V₁₂<0) and the dynamics is monotone (or oscillating). We then encompass the separable case, u₁₂i=0 and extend the result to the cases where marginal utility of the babies is a decreasing function i.e death occurrence is coupled with a weakly increasing function of the mothers health state in particular if V₁₂≤0. Finally, if the curvature of the production function is given, an adequate increase of the utility function's degree of concavity may lead to a positive cross derivative V₁₂ and the dynamics is monotone. Thus, there exists a trade-off between the degrees of concavity of f and u. Oscillating paths may be obtained if the production function is more concave than the instantaneous utility function specifically when medical treatment efficiency is less strong than the virus action in health alteration.
A sustainable growth in lives path: necessarily satisfies the Euler-Lagrange equation i.e
(2.8)
Let ai*=f(ki*)-sci* be the sustainable steady state associated to the indirect optimal function, Vij*=Vij*(a* ,a*)I,j=1,2. The roots of the Jacobian matrix associated with the linearization of the previous equation evaluated at (ai*, ai*) will be the solution of the characteristic polynomial
(2.9)
To study local stability of the steady state, we need the following definition:
Definition1: An optimal steady state (ai*, ai*) of the Euler Lagrange equation reaches the sustainable path if the two roots λ of the previous characteristic polynomial are such that one is strictly inside (-1,1) and the other is strictly outside.
This definition allows us to sue the saddle point stability which is usually employed in the optimal growth literature. In this model, the existence of a root strictly inside ensures the existence of a one dimensional stable manifold. Following Scheinkman lemma, under the assumption of strict concavity, the projection of the stable manifold on the space (ati, at+1i) is a local diffeomorphism. Then for each initial value ai close to ai*, there exists an unique a such that (a0i, ai) is on the stable manifold and the optimal path converges to the steady state. Our model is symmetric i.e V₁₂=V₂₁ and thus all roots provided by the characteristic polynomial are real. From Benhabib-Nishimura, we have the following theorem.
Theorem1: the steady state (ai*, ai*) is the optimal sustainable path if and only if:
(2.10)
Note that: because V is strictly concave, if δ=1 the previous condition holds and the saddle point exists. Otherwise if δ<1 then the indirect utility function strict concavity is no more guarantee and the dynamics oscillates.
Proposition4: If the instantaneous utility function ui is such that
u₁₂(smi, sci)<0, then the steady state (ai*,ai*) is a regular saddle point if and only if:
(2.11)
PROOF: if u₁₂(smi, sci)<0 then V21*>0 indeed the condition of theorem1 becomes
Replacing A,B,C by their respective values, the previous equation becomes
where Hi≥0
Let us consider now the case of oscillating dynamics i.e when V₁₂=-u₁₂i+BC/(A-f′′ui)<0 the production function needs to be concave with respect to the instantaneous utility function. We already know that u₁₂(smi, sci)0 is a necessary condition for V₂₁<0. Moreover, lemma 1 shows that there exists a trade-off between the degrees of concavity of f and ui. Therefore V₂₁<0 is obtained when the production function is concave with respect to the instantaneous utility function. Therefore we can announce a necessary and sufficient condition for the saddle point property of the steady state.
Proposition5: assuming that the instantaneous utility function u₁₂(smi,sci)≻0 and satisfies with the production function condition i.e -f′Hi-f′′u₂ iu₂₂ i≻0 where Hi≥0 is the determinant of the Hessian matrix of ui evaluated at (smi,sci), then the steady state (ai*,ai*) is a regular saddle point if and only if:
PROOF: under the assumption of the proposition5 i.e u₁₂(smi, sci)0 we have V₁₂<0, the condition for the saddle point existence is:
under the assumptions of the proposition we have V12<0, the condition of theorem 1 is thus,
given the values of B, C, A the previous expression is equivalent to
and Since f’=δ¹ and Hi≥0, proposition 5 is verified. Note that if Hi=0, the stability condition becomes

2.4. Flip bifurcation and Competitive Cycles in a Non Separable Case

Under the assumption of V₁₂<0 we know that optimal paths are oscillating. If the condition of theorem 1 doesn't hold, then there exists a bifurcation value δ* which generates two period cycles. Consequently, if V₁₂<0 we have a flip bifurcation which generates two period cycles.
Definition2: δ* is a flip bifurcation value if locally on one side there exist two period cycles and not on the other side. According to assumptions 1 and 2, the saddle point stability provided by theorem 1 is satisfied when δ=1 and leads to the following theorem of Cartigny and Venditti
Theorem2: If V₁₂(ai,bi) is strictly negative, then there exist a flip bifurcation value δ*ε(0,1) if and only if the sign of changes when δ crosses δ*
Proposition6: Assume that the instantaneous utility function ui is such that ui(smi, sci)0 and satisfies with the production function -f′Hi-f′′uiu₂₂i0 when Hi≥0 is the determinant of the Hessian matrix evaluated at (smi, sci) then there exist a flip bifurcation value δ*ε(0,1) if and only if the sign of:
changes when δ crosses δ*.
Note that if the instantaneous utility function is not too concave in the neighborhood of the steady state (i.e Hi* is close to zero) whereas the production function is highly concave (i.e |f′′| is high enough), the condition of proposition 5 may be satisfied especially if Hi*=0, the condition becomes, the sign of changes when δ crosses δ*

3. Application of the Theory

3.1. The Additively Separable Case

We assume that the non infected pregnant women have an additively separable utility function expressed such that:
(3.1)
where 0<β<1 is the elasticity of the baby
The production function is expressed such that
(3.2)
where θЄ(0,1).
Proposition7: the additively separable utility, (3.1) and the production functions (3.2) define the stable optimal solution composed of the vector of variables expressed by (3)-(6) i.e
(3.3)
(3.4)
(3.5)
(3.6)
Proof: we know that, on the one hand, u is concave because u11<0 ,u22<0 and u12=u21=0. On the other hand, f is concave because f’>0 and f’’<0 , therefore the optimal solution exist and is unique.
According to the theory, we have presented above, u1=(1+r)u2 and smh+smc=f(k)-k ; 1+r=f’=1/δ which yield stationary values of production, capital stocks and consumptions expressed by (3)-(6)
Growth in life expectancy gain is thus expressed by equation (3.7) which yields
(3.7)
Life is expressed by the difference between young and old rates such that population growth increases when the elasticity of the babies is higher than that of the discount rate or the economic growth rate.
In order to study the cases where the mothers are infected while waiting for new born, we need to introduce additional assumptions.
Assuming γm to be the mother's HIV/AIDS infection risk parameter and γc be the HIV/AIDS transmission risk from the mother to the child parameter, if γm0 then i.e the mother’s health state is conditioned on the pandemic prevalence. Therefore we have i.e the baby’s health state depends on his mother’s infection gravity. Indeed, , it is no more possible to separate functionally the mother and the baby variables because for two given scalars λ1 and λ2 , such that we cannot have λ12 =0 for those variables to be expressed freely and taking the utility function we have . Indeed , the additively separable utility function uth(stmh, st+1ch) converges to the non separable utility function uti(stmi, st+1ci) which oscillates in life duration over time.

3.2. The Oscillatory Dynamics

The utility function is now of Cobb Douglas i.e it is no more additively separable and expressed such that equation (8) i.e:
(3.8)
The production function is almost the same as before i.e
(3.9)
. Using the same formulas as before with , the stationary values of production, capital stocks and consumptions are expressed such that:
(3.10)
(3.11)
(3.12)
(3.13)
Population growth is given by
(3.14)
Compare to the previous case, population growth depends now on the pandemic prevalence essentially in Africa, specifically on the mother’s infection gravity. If the pandemic is transmitted, then the economic growth represented by the discount factor is higher. The aim of the following discussion is to reduce the uncertainty in life gift and HIV/AIDS prevalence in establishing conditions for which optimal growth in life terms exist.
3.2.1. Study of the Sign of the Cross Derivative of u
(3.15)
If γc<0 and γm<0 we have u12<0, then the steady state is reached. Otherwise if γc>0 and γm>0, we have u12>0.
From lemma 1, if γc<0 and γm<0, then optimal paths are monotone because u12 <0. Otherwise, if γcm=1 and γc>0 , γm>0, we have Hi = 0 and the optimal dynamics is oscillating. Finally if γcm<1 , we have: . Therefore, it is necessary to study the sign of V12 in the neighborhood of the steady state. It follows that
(3.16)
Since f’(k*)=δ-1 , the previous inequality is equivalent to
is a monotone decreasing function. Thus depending on the values of γc , γm and θ, if h(1)<0 then V12>0 for all values of the discount factor on (0,1]. Specifically, if θ>γm /1-γc i.e medical care is high, the optimal dynamics is monotone for all values of δ or the economic growth rate, this condition is satisfied only if γc and γm are small enough i.e the utility function is highly concave. Otherwise if medical care is insufficient i.e θ<γm/1-γc , there must be established an optimal economic growth rate δ* such that h(δ*)=0 to ensure population growth stability i.e:
(3.17)
But optimal paths oscillate for all δ<δ*
If δ*>1 i.e the economic stability level is too high enough meaning:
if then V12<0 for all values of the discount factor in (0,1] because the system is increasing in per-capita income while population growth is reducing. This condition is also satisfied when γcγm is too high. Otherwise if δ*Є (0,1), the optimal dynamics is monotone only if δЄ(δ*,1]. Then, if the curvature of the production function or health care provision is given, an increase of the utility function’s degree of concavity leads to a positive cross derivative V12. The existence of oscillating paths requires that the production function is concave enough with respect to the instantaneous utility function.
3.2.2. Study of Local Stability of the Steady State
If γcγm<0 , optimal paths are monotone because we have u12<0, it yields:
Because we have
for all δЄ(0,1]. Then, the steady state is a regular saddle point for all values of the discount factor δЄ(0,1]
Otherwise, if γcγm>0 and γcm ≤1 , the optimal path is oscillating i.e we have u12 >0 and it depends on the concavity properties of f and u. The required condition given in proposition 5 is that
Since γcm-1≤0 we conclude that if
(3.18)
The optimality condition is satisfied.
Let S=γcm≤1 , it follows and we obtain
(3.19)
Several conclusions may be given from the above two inequalities
-If γc<1/2 and γm≤1/2 , the saddle point stability is satisfied for all values of the discount factor δЄ(0,1]
-If γc>1/2 and γm≤1/2 with γcm≤1 , the stability condition is also satisfied for all values of the discount factor δЄ(0,1]. Indeed the sufficient condition (3.18) becomes =δ* and it follows from (3.19) that δ*≥1
- If γc<1/2 and γm ≥1/2 with γcm≤1 , the sufficient condition becomes δ>δ* i.e economic growth is higher than the equilibrium rate. Indeed the stability condition is satisfied for all δЄ(δ*,1] such that δ*<1
In oscillating optimal paths in lives terms, the condition of existence of two periods cycles is given by:
(3.20)
If γcm<1 , the instantaneous utility function is more and more concave, the two period cycles exist for more and more extreme values of the discount factor
If γcm=1 , the determinant of the hessian matrix is zero i.e Hi=0 , the above condition becomes
(3.21)
If γm>1/2 , we obtain , in contrast to the previous case, now if the utility function is homogenous, cycles may exist for δ close to 1. Indeed, it is sufficient to adequately modify the values of γm toward ½ and then δ* tends toward 1.

4. Conclusions

In this paper, we have first proved that in an overlapping generation model with one production sector, if the utility function of health state summarized by per-capita mother and baby is non separable, then optimal steady state in lives terms is not necessarily reached. Depending on the HIV/AIDS gravity and transmission risk and it may appear cycles and hopf bifurcation at critical locus. Applying a specific Cobb Douglas utility function, the event is measured through the comparison between the discount factor which is assimilated to the economic growth rate and population growth of life occurrences view through the HIV/AIDS parameters fluctuations during the pregnancy process. We found that optimal life dynamics existence and stability depend on illness gravity and medical care investment interaction.

ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS

The author is an experienced researcher in development economics and wishes to thanks the Editor of the journal and the anonymous Referees for helpful comments, errors and misunderstandings are solely mines.

Note

1. The function is taken on Michelle-Venditti (1994)

References

[1]  2006 Report on the global AIDS epidemic. Geneva, UNAIDS, 2006 (http://www.unaids.org/
[2]  Questions & Answers, Geneva, UNAIDS, November 2005 (http://www.unaids.org/
[3]  De Cock KM et al. Prevention of mother-to-child HIV transmission in resource-poor countries: translating research into policy and practice. Journal of the American Medical Association, 2000, 283(9):1175–1182.
[4]  Read J et al. A prospective cohort study of HIV-1-infected pregnant women and their infants in Latin America and the Caribbean: the NICHD International Site Development Initiative Perinatal Study. 12th Conference on Retroviruses and Opportunistic Infections. Boston, MA, USA. 22–25 February 2005
[5]  Mother-to-child transmission of HIV infection in the era of highly active antiretroviral therapy. Clinical Infectious Diseases, 2005, 40(3):458–465.
[6]  Dorenbaum A et al. Two-dose intrapartum/newborn nevirapine and standard antiretroviral therapy to reduce perinatal HIV transmission: a randomized trial. Journal of the American Medical Association, 2002, 288(2):189–198.
[7]  Songok EM et al. The use of short-course zidovudine to prevent perinatal transmission of human immunodefi ciency virus in rural Kenya. The American Journal of Tropical Medicine and Hygiene, 2003, 69(1):8–13.
[8]  McIntyre J et al. Addition of short course combivir (CBV) to single dose viramune (sdNVP) for the prevention of mother to child transmission (PMTCT) of HIV-1 can signifi cantly decrease the subsequent development of maternal and paediatric NNRTI-resistant virus. The 3rd IAS Conference on HIV Pathogenesis and Treatment. Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 24–27 July 2005
[9]  Cooper ER et al. Combination antiretroviral strategies for the treatment of pregnant HIV-1- infected women and prevention of perinatal HIV-1 transmission. Journal of Acquired Immune Deficiency Syndromes, 2002, 29(5):484–494.
[10]  Centers for Disease Control and Prevention. Public Health Service task force recommendations for use of antiretroviral drugs in pregnant women infected with HIV-1 for maternal health and for reducing perinatal HIV-1 transmission in the United States. Morbidity and Mortality Weekly Report, 1998, 47
[11]  AIDS info. Public Health Service Task Forcerecommendations for use of antiretroviral drugs in pregnant HIV-1-infected women for maternal health and interventions to reduce perinatal HIV-1 transmission in the United States. Rockville, MD, US Department of Health and Human Services, 17 November, 2005
[12]  Ramsey, F., P., 1928, A mathematical theory of savings, Economic Theory Journal, 38, 543-559
[13]  Cass, D., 1965, Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation, The Review of Economic Studies, 32, 233-240
[14]  Koopmans , T.,1965, On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth, Cowles Foundation Paper 238, Reprinted from Academiae Scientiarum Scripta Varia 28, 1
[15]  Blanchard, O., J. and Fischer, S., 1989, Lectures on macroeconomics, MIT Press
[16]  Collier and Obstfield, 1982, International Economics: Theory and Policy
[17]  Cass, D. and Shell, K., 1976, Introduction to Hamiltonian Dynamics in Economics, Journal of Economic Theory, 12, 1-10
[18]  Benhabibb, J. and Nishimura, K., 1979, The Hopf Bifurcation and the existence and stability of closed orbits in multisector models of optimal economic growths, Journal of Economic Theory, 21, 421-444
[19]  Benhabibb, J. and Nishimura, K., 1985, CompetitiveEquilibrium Cycles, Journal of Economic Theory, 35, 284-306
[20]  Boldrin and Montrucchio 1987, Acyclicity and Dynamic Stability : Generalizations and Applications, Working Paper N 980
[21]  Sorger, G., 1990, An optimal steady states of n sectors growth models when utility is discounted, Journal of Economic Theory, 65, 321-329
[22]  Benhabibb, J. and Nishimura, K., 1985, CompetitiveEquilibrium Cycles, Journal of Economic Theory, 35, 284-306
[23]  Cuddington, J. T. and Hancock., J. D., 1995, “The Macroeconomic Impact of AIDS in Malawi: A Dualistic Labor Surplus Economy.”, Journal of African Economies, Vol 4, pp.1-28.
[24]  Cuddington, J.T. and Hancock, J. T.. and Rogers. C. A., 1994, “A Dynamic Aggregative Model of the AIDS Epidemic with Possible Policy Interventions.” Journal of Policy Modeling Vol.16, pp.473-496.
[25]  Cuddington, J. T. and Hancock. ,J. D. 1994, “Assessing the Impact of AIDS on the Growth Path of the Malawian Economy”, Journal of Developing Economics, Vol 43, pp.363-368.
[26]  Kambou, G., Devarajan, S. and Over, M., 1993, “TheEconomic Impact of AIDS in an African Country: Simulations with a General Equilibrium Model of Cameroon, ”Journal of African Economies, Vol.1, No.1, pp. 103-130.
[27]  Theodore, K., 2001, HIV/AIDS in the Caribbean economic, Center for International development, WHO
[28]  Silva A et al. Prevention of mother-to-child HIV transmission in Luanda, Angola-Africa. 3rd IAS Conference on HIV Pathogenesis and Treatment. Rio de Janeiro, Brazil, 24–27 July 2005
[29]  Young, A., 2005, In Sorrow to Bring Forth Children: Fertility amidst the Plague of HIV, University of Chicago.
[30]  Haaker, M. ed. 2004, “The Macroeconomics of AIDS,” Washington: International Monetary Fund.
[31]  Arndt, Channing. 2006. “Review of ‘The macroeconomics of HIV/AIDS’”. Journal of African Economies.
[32]  Tonwe-Gold B et al. Highly active antiretroviral therapy for the prevention of perinatal HIV transmission in Africa: mother-to-child HIV transmission plus, Abidjan, Côte d’Ivoire, 2003–2004. 12th Conference on Retroviruses and Opportunistic Infections. Boston, MA, USA, 22–25 February 2005
[33]  Bachmann Max O. and Frederick L. R. Booysen, 2003. “Health and economic impact of HIV/AIDS on South African households: a cohort study.” BMC Public Health 3:14.
[34]  Bachmann Max O and Frederick L. R. Booysen. 2004. “Relationships between HIV/AIDS,income and expenditure over time in deprived South African households.” AIDS Care 16(7):817-826.
[35]  Bechu, N. 1998. “The impact of AIDS on the economy of families in Côte d’Ivoire: Changes in consumption among AIDS-affected households,” in M. Ainsworth, L. Fransen and M. Over (eds.), Confronting AIDS: Evidence from the developing world: Selected background papers for the World Bank Policy Research Report. Brussels: European Commission.
[36]  Bollinger, Lori, Katharine Cooper-Arnold and John Stover. 2004. “Where Are the Gaps? The Effects of HIV-prevention Interventions on Behavioral Change.” Studies in Family Planning 35(1):27-38.
[37]  Bollinger, Lori, John Stover, R. Kerkhoven, G. Mutangadura and D. Mukurazita. 1999. The Economic Impact of AIDS in Zimbabwe. Washington, D.C.: Futures Group/Research Triangle Institute/Centre for Development and Population Activities.
[38]  Gregson, Simon, Phyllis Mushati, Constance Nyamukapa. 2006b. “Adult Mortality and Erosion of Household Viability in AIDS-Afflicted Towns, Estates, and Villages in Eastern Zimbabwe” Journal of Acquired Immune Deficiency Syndrome 44(2):188-195.
[39]  Jayne, T. S., Villarreal1, M. and Hemrich, G., 2005, HIV/AIDS and the Agricultural Sector: Implications for Policy in Eastern and Southern Africa, Journal of Agricultural and Development Economics, Vol. 2, No. 2, 2005, pp. 158-181
[40]  Ngalula, J., M. Urassa, G. Mwaluko, R. Isingo and J. Ties Boerma. 2002. “Health service use and household expenditure during terminal illness due to AIDS in rural Tanzania.” Trop Med Int Health 7(10):873-877.
[41]  Over, Mead, Martha Ainsworth, et al. 1996. Coping with AIDS: The Economic Impact of Adult Mortality from AIDS and Other Causes on Households in Kagera, Tanzania. Washington, DC:World Bank.
[42]  Over, Mead. 1999. “The Public Interest in a Private Disease,” in King K. Holmes, P. Frederick Sparling, Per-Anders Mardh, Stanley M Lemon, Walter E. Stamm, Peter Piot, Judith N. Wasserheit (eds Transmitted Diseases. New York: McGraw
[43]  Loubaki, D., 2012a, On the mechanics of the diseases reduction in poorest developing countries, Journal of Economics and Sustainable Development, Vol.3, No.8, pp.37-51.
[44]  Loubaki, D., 2012b, What strategy for optimal health in poorest developing countries, Journal of Developing Countries Studies, 2(7), 1-10.
[45]  Loubaki, D., 2012c, Optimal growth with HIV/AIDS and food crisis in Sub-Saharan Africa, Asian Journal of Scientific Research, 2(9), 436-444.
[46]  Loubaki, D., 2013, Technological Change and Healthcare/ Food Interaction Policy in Development Economics, American Journal of Food and Nutrition, Vol. 1, No. 2, 7-11
[47]  Waziri, A. S., Massawe, E. S. and Makinde, O. D., 2012, Mathematical modeling of HIV/AIDS dynamics with treatment and vertical transmission, Journal of Applied Mathematics, 2(3), 77-89
[48]  Goldstein, M; Zivin, J. G.; Habyarimania, J.; Pop-Eleches, C. and Thirumurthy, H.; 2013, The effect of absenteeism and clinic protocol on health outcomes: The case of mother to child transmission of HIV in Kenya, American Economic Journal, 5(2), 58-85
[49]  Michel, P. and Venditti, A., 1997, Optimal growth and cycles in Overlapping generations models, Economic Theory Journal, 9, 511-528
[50]  Goenka, A. and Liu, .L., 2012, Infectiuos disease and endogenous fluctuations, Economic Theory Journal, 50, 125-149